Group Composition and Cooperation

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Group Composition and Cooperation"

Transcription

1 Group Composition and Cooperation Alexander Smith May 15, 2009 Abstract This paper presents an experiment designed to measure how heterogeneous identity affects contributions in a voluntary contribution mechanism (VCM) linear public good game. Identity was induced using a team-building activity and then subjects were assigned to groups consisting of a varying number of subjects from each team. Majority members generally made higher contributions than minority members. In addition, beliefs about the contributions of group members from the same team were a stronger determinant of behaviour than beliefs about the contributions of group members from the other team. Keywords: Public Good Game; Group Identity; Altruism; Reciprocity Classification Codes: C9 The author thanks Subhasish Dugar, Robert Oxoby and Jennifer Winter. PhD Candidate, Department of Economics, University of Calgary, 2500 University Drive NW, Calgary AB Canada T2N 1N4; smithad@ucalgary.ca; tel , fax

2 1 Introduction From neighbours helping each other with outdoor projects to the nations that are members of the world s trade organizations, cooperation has the potential to make everyone better off. However, cooperation varies across individuals and environments. For example, evidence suggests that being a member of a minority group or having low income reduces participation in community activities such as groups and clubs (Alesina and La Ferrara, 2000). The same study finds that income inequality and ethnic diversity (at the community level) decrease participation. Related research suggests that spending on public goods including education, roads, sewers and waste removal is decreasing in ethnic fragmentation in US metropolitan areas (Alesina et al., 1999). Unfortunately for policy-makers aiming to correct the inefficiencies, it is not clear how heterogeneity reduces people s willingness to cooperate. To address the issue, this paper studies cooperation using an experiment based on the public good game of Isaac et al. (1984). Cooperation is measured by the amount of money subjects contribute to a public account. While contributions to the public account earn a return and increase the total surplus of the group, they decrease the payoff of the contributor. The aim is to determine how heterogeneity affects cooperation and ultimately, the efficiency of public good provision. The results suggest that in heterogeneous groups, majority members contribute more than minority members, and beliefs about the contributions of similar group members strongly affect behaviour. The provision of public goods is an important part of daily life throughout modern society. People benefit from public goods ranging from environmental quality such as clean air and water to protection in the form of national defense. In many developed countries, services including education and health care are non-excludable and thus exhibit characteristics of public goods as well. The social capital literature suggests that social cohesion supporting the provision of public goods promotes economic activity 2

3 and development (Glaeser et al., 2002; Putnam, 2000). For example, Knack and Keefer (1997) find that increased trust at a national level is associated with higher annual growth rates. However, Zak and Knack (2001) provide evidence that trust is adversely affected by population heterogeneity such as income inequality and ethnic diversity. This paper uses an experiment to determine how heterogeneous identity affects cooperation. Identity was induced using a team-building activity, as in Eckel and Grossman (2005) and McLeish and Oxoby (2007), and then subjects were assigned to groups consisting of a varying number of subjects from each team. Groups of six consisted of either five subjects from one team and one from the other, four subjects from one team and two from the other, or three subjects from each team. Subjects played a repeated voluntary contribution mechanism (VCM) linear public good game as in Isaac et al. (1984). In addition to making contribution decisions in each round, subjects were asked how much they believed the other subjects from their team and from the other team would contribute. Repetition of the public good game with rematching in each round meant that subjects served as majority and minority members, and allowed for the updating of beliefs. Aggregate contributions vary as a function of group composition and are highest when groups consist of four subjects from one team and two from the other. Individual contributions are increasing in the number of group members sharing the subject s team affiliation and beliefs about the contributions of other group members. However, beliefs about the contributions of group members from the same team have a larger effect on behaviour than beliefs about the contributions of group members from the other team. In addition, subjects base their beliefs on the expectation that other subjects make contributions increasing in the number of group members with whom they share the same team affiliation and that subjects make contributions similar to the amounts previously contributed by other subjects of the same type. 3

4 The findings build on previous research examining how identity affects cooperation in public good games. Eckel and Grossman (2005), for example, find that promoting a common identity within a homogeneous group increases contributions. Castro (2006) studies heterogeneous groups by matching two subjects of one nationality with two subjects of another and finds a decrease in contributions compared to when groups are homogeneous. A primary contribution of this paper is to explore the interaction of majority and minority group members. In this regard, the paper extends the work of Oxoby and Spraggon (2006), who consider heterogeneity with respect to the source of endowments and find that aggregate contributions decrease in the presence of a minority. The results also provide evidence about the role of altruism and reciprocity in determining cooperation. Some experiments (Andreoni, 1988; 2005) suggest that altruism is the main determinant of contributions in public good games while others (Croson, 2007; Fischbacher et al., 2001) find that positive contributions are primarily because of reciprocity. This experiment suggests that altruism and reciprocity are both important. Altruism has a direct effect on contributions and influences subject s beliefs about the contributions of others, which affect cooperation due to reciprocity effects. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the literature on public good experiments, focusing on papers examining the effects of heterogeneity. Section 3 describes the experiment and develops hypotheses motivated by altruism and reciprocity. Section 4 presents results and section 5 concludes. 2 Related Literature Isaac et al. (1984) are among the first to use a public good game to study cooperation. Subjects are assigned to groups of four or ten members and provided with endowments 4

5 of tokens in each of ten rounds of play. In each round, subjects decide how many tokens to keep for themselves and how many to contribute to a community account. The contributions, which serve as the measure of cooperation, are added up and multiplied by 0.3 or 0.75 to determine the amount returned to each group member. 1 The Nash equilibrium (under the assumption of individual wealth maximization) is to contribute nothing, but the total surplus is maximized when everyone contributes their whole endowment. Subjects contribute an average of 42%, and while MPCR positively affects contributions, the effect of group size is small. The results of Isaac et al. (1984) are very robust. 2 However, there are multiple explanations for subjects willingness to cooperate. Andreoni examines the roles of strategy (1988) and confusion (1995) and concludes that altruism is an important factor determining contributions. Related research studies altruism in Prisoner s Dilemma games (Andreoni and Miller, 1993; Cooper et al., 1996). Many experiments consider heterogeneity between subjects. Fisher (1995) finds that in groups consisting of subjects with different MPCRs, subjects make contributions increasing in their MPCR. Other authors investigate heterogeneity in income (Buckley and Croson, 2006; Chan et al., 1996), where income is the amount subjects receive at the start of each round. They find that low income subjects contribute similar absolute amounts to high income subjects, who contribute relatively smaller shares of their endowment. Chan et al. (1999) report a positive interaction effect between income heterogeneity and heterogeneity in preferences for a non-linear public good. Buckley and Croson (2006) find that subjects are unaffected by wealth, captured by accumulated earnings. Cherry et al. (2005) report a decrease in aggregate contributions when endowments 1 The multiplier is often referred to as the Marginal Per Capita Return (MPCR). 2 See Ledyard (1995) for a survey of the literature on public good experiments. 5

6 are heterogeneous. They show that the finding is robust to the origin of endowments, which are either randomly assigned or earned by performing well on a quiz. However, all subjects in each group have the same source of endowments. In contrast, Oxoby and Spraggon (2006) consider heterogeneity with respect to the origin of endowments and find that when two of four subjects in a group earn their endowment (as opposed to having it randomly assigned), contributions are similar to when groups are homogeneous. When one subject has an endowment of a different origin from the other three subjects, contributions decline. Other research studies heterogeneity between subjects not affecting the pecuniary costs and benefits of making contributions to the public account. For example, Anderson et al. (2008) give subjects unequal show-up payments, but provide them with homogeneous endowments to use in the public good game. Contributions are lower than when subjects receive the same show-up fee. Ruffle and Sosis (2006) find that members of the Israeli kibbutz are more cooperative when they are grouped with each other than with city residents. A related experiment by Castro (2006) finds that contributions decrease when British and Italian subjects are grouped together. Ruffle and Sosis (2006) and Castro (2006) address the issue of how heterogeneous identity affects cooperation. Germane to this topic is the work of Eckel and Grossman (2005) who find that creating and promoting a common identity among subjects increases cooperation in public good games. Their paper is part of a growing literature about identity including theoretical and experimental research. Akerlof and Kranton (2000) propose that identity influences behaviour because utility is a function of the affiliations people share with those affected by their actions. Chen and Li (forthcoming) test the predictions of Akerlof and Kranton s (2000) model using a series of simple two-person sequential games to estimate a model of social preference incorporating identity. The games measuring reciprocity (Dufwenberg and Kirchsteiger, 2004; Rabin, 6

7 1993) suggest that subjects are more likely to reward in-group members (as opposed to out-group members) for positive treatment and less likely to punish them for negative treatment, leading Chen and Li to conclude that positive reciprocity is stronger among those sharing the same affiliations. In the context of a public good game, reciprocity is captured by the relationship between contributions and beliefs about the contributions of other group members (Dufwenberg, 2008). A number of experiments suggest that reciprocity is an important motive for cooperation. Fischbacher et al. (2001) find that while many subjects are free-riders, most are what they term conditional cooperators. That is, they are willing to contribute more when the average contribution of the other group members is higher. Subsequent experiments suggest that beliefs about the contributions of other group members positively affect individual contributions (Croson, 2007; Fischbacher and Gachter, 2006). 3 The Experiment The experiment used a repeated VCM linear public good game similar to the game of Isaac et al. (1984). Group composition was manipulated across three treatments. All treatments began by dividing subjects into two teams as they arrived at the experiment. Each team was placed in a separate room and asked to answer a quiz consisting of twenty questions. The quiz was casual in nature and involved unscrambling jumbled letters to make words and determining the next number in a sequence of numbers. The teams were allowed to submit only one answer sheet per team, so team members had to interact while answering the quiz. The aim was for each team to develop a common identity. The process was similar to the identity-building activity used by McLeish and Oxoby (2007). While identity can be induced in a variety of 7

8 ways, it is often the case that only strong mechanisms such as group tasks influence subsequent behaviour (Eckel and Grossman, 2005). If a team answered at least twelve of the twenty questions on the quiz correctly, each member received a payment of $5, otherwise each member received nothing. 3 Following the quiz, subjects played twelve rounds of the public good game using endowments of $10. In Treatment 1, groups consisted of a single minority subject from one team and a five subject majority from the other team. At the start of each round, groups were re-matched to eliminate the incentives for dynamic strategies such as signaling the intention to make high contributions (Andreoni, 1988) and punishing low contributions (Fehr and Gachter, 2000). The re-matching occurred in a manner such that each subject was a minority member twice and a majority member ten times over the course of the twelve rounds of the experiment. Subjects who were minorities in a given round are labeled type 1 and subjects who were majority members are labeled type 5. Subjects were informed of their minority or majority status before making any decisions. In each round, subjects decided how much of their endowment to keep and how much to contribute to the community account. In addition, minority members were asked to guess the average contribution of the majority members. This guess was their out-group belief. Majority subjects were asked to guess the contribution of the minority subject (their out-group belief) and the average contribution of their fellow majority members (their in-group belief). Soliciting beliefs about the contributions of other subjects has become a common feature of public good experiments aiming to explain contribution decisions (Croson, 2007; Dufwenberg et al., 2008; Fischbacher and Gachter, 2006). Once the subjects had made all their choices, the contributions of the 3 All teams were successful on the quiz so all subjects had the same accumulated earnings when they played the public good game. However, it is not possible to determine how success on the quiz affects choices in the public good game. 8

9 six group members were added up and multiplied by two. The total was divided by six to determine each subject s share of the community account, which was added to the amount they kept initially to determine their payoff. The payoff of each subject is given by: 6 π ir = 10 C ir C jr (1) j=1 where C ir is the contribution of subject i in round r and the summation of contributions is taken over the six group members indexed by j. Following the calculation of the payoffs, the subjects were informed of their payoff and the average contributions of their in-group and out-group members. Subjects received $1 for each belief within $1 of the actual amount, making their earnings in each round the sum of their payoff from the public good game and up to $2 for correct beliefs. At the completion of the twelve rounds, one round was randomly selected to determine each subject s final earnings, which were the sum of a $5 payment for success on the quiz and their earnings in the randomly selected round. The payment mechanism meant that earnings could not be accumulated across rounds; subjects played each round using their initial endowment of $10. This ensured that decisions were not influenced by any possible wealth effects due to accumulated earnings. 4 In Treatment 2, groups consisted of two minority members labeled type 2 and four majority members labeled type 4. Each subject was a minority member four times and a majority member eight times during the twelve rounds. Both types of subject were asked their in-group and out-group beliefs in each round, but in all other respects, the decision-making proceeded in the same manner as in Treatment 1. All subjects in Treatment 3 were type 3 subjects and there were no minority or majority members. However, subjects were once again re-matched in each round and asked their in-group and out-group beliefs, as in Treatments 1 and 2. 4 Note that Buckley and Croson (2006) find no significant effect of accumulated earnings (wealth). 9

10 To summarize the definition of type, a subject s type is given by tɛ {1, 2, 3, 4, 5} where t refers to the number of subjects in their group with their team affiliation. Hypotheses Theories of altruism and reciprocity incorporating identity motivate hypotheses for the experiment. The experiments of Andreoni (1988, 1995) provide evidence altruism plays a role in determining public good contributions. In addition, the literature on identity argues individuals are more altruistic toward those with whom they share affiliations (Chen and Li, forthcoming; Simpson, 2006). According to this reasoning, subjects sharing the same team affiliation with a larger number of group members have a stronger incentive to be altruistic and should make higher contributions. This suggests the following: Hypothesis 1: Contributions are increasing in a subject s type. That is, C ir(t) t > 0. In general, majority members are expected to contribute more than minority members. Specifically, Hypothesis 1 predicts that C ir (1) < C ir (2) < C ir (3) < C ir (4) < C ir (5). However, Hypothesis 1 does not predict the differences in contributions between subject types. As a result, it is not clear which Treatment will have the highest aggregate contributions (given that Treatment 1 consists of type 1 and 5 subjects, Treatment 2 of type 2 and 4 subjects and Treatment 3 of only type 3 subjects). While altruism provides a simple hypothesis regarding individual contributions, more recent evidence suggests reciprocity as an alternative explanation for public good game results (Croson, 2007). Experiments show that subjects make contributions conditional on the contributions of others (Fischbacher et al., 2001) and contribute more when they believe others are contributing high amounts (Croson, 2007; Fischbacher and Gachter). Also, identity experiments find that reciprocity effects are stronger among 10

11 in-group members than out-group members (Chen and Li, forthcoming; McLeish and Oxoby, 2007). This suggests that subjects should contribute more when they believe their in-group members are contributing high amounts. The same effect may exist for out-group members, but would be less pronounced. Therefore, we have: Hypothesis 2: Contributions are increasing in a subject s in-group belief, and to a lesser degree, in their out-group belief. Hypothesis 2 predicts relationships between contributions and in-group and outgroup beliefs. However, it is not clear what determines a subject s beliefs. A possibility is that subjects initially believe others are altruistic in the manner captured by Hypothesis 1. This suggests that majority (minority) members will believe in-group (out-group) members will make high contributions and out-group (in-group) members will make low contributions. Of course, given the repeated nature of the public good game, it is expected that as the rounds progress, beliefs will be determined primarily by experience in previous rounds. 4 Results The experiment was conducted at our University s experimental economics laboratory using subjects recruited from the undergraduate student body. The decision-making rounds were programmed in z-tree (Fischbacher, 2007) and occurred over a closedcircuit computer network. Three sessions were conducted using a total of 36 subjects. Each session lasted about 75 minutes and average earnings were $19.45 with a standard deviation of $3.56. The minimum earnings were $12.70 and the maximum was $ The 36 subjects each made twelve contribution decisions generating a total of 432 observations. Average contributions in each round are plotted by subject type in Figures 11

12 1-3. Figure 1: Average Contributions in Treatment Contribution Type 5 Type Round Figure 2: Average Contributions in Treatment Contribution Type 4 Type Round 12

13 Figure 3: Average Contributions in Treatment 3 Contribution Round Type 3 The average contribution of type 5 subjects is decreasing with repetition. The average contribution of type 1 subjects is more volatile because there are only two observations from each round. For the most part, the trend for type 5 subjects lies above the trend for type 1 subjects. Average contributions in Treatment 2 are decreasing, but not as sharply as for type 5 subjects. Type 2 and type 4 subjects contributed more than in previous rounds on multiple occasions. The trend for type 4 subjects lies almost entirely above the trend for type 2 subjects. The trend in Treatment 3 is negative and fairly smooth. Average in-group and out-group beliefs in each round are plotted by subject type in Figures

14 Figure 4: Average Beliefs in Treatment 1 Belief Round Type 5 (In-group) Type 5 (Out-group) Type 1 (Out-group) Figure 5: Average Beliefs in Treatment 2 Belief Round Type 4 (In-group) Type 4 (Out-group) Type 2 (In-group) Type 2 (Out-group) 14

15 Figure 6: Average Beliefs in Treatment 3 Belief Round Type 3 (In-group) Type 3 (Out-group) Beliefs are decreasing with repetition in Treatment 1. The average in-group belief of type 5 subjects is higher than the average out-group belief in every round, indicating that type 5 subjects consistently thought their fellow majority members would contribute more than the minority member in their group. This suggests that type 5 subjects had beliefs consistent with the prediction of Hypothesis 1, that contributions are increasing in a subject s type. The average out-group belief of type 1 subjects is similar to the average in-group belief of type 5 subjects, suggesting that minority and majority members had similar expectations regarding the contributions of majority members. Beliefs are decreasing less with repetition in Treatment 2 than in Treatment 1. Type 4 subjects had in-group beliefs higher than their out-group beliefs while type 2 subjects were mostly the opposite, often thinking that in-group members would contribute less than out-group members. These observations provide evidence that type 2 and 4 subjects also had beliefs consistent with Hypothesis 1. The average in-group and out-group 15

16 beliefs of type 3 subjects are approximately equal in each round. However, in the first four rounds, type 3 subjects had a small bias toward thinking that in-group members would be more altruistic than out-group members. The amounts contributed are pooled across rounds and summary statistics are given in Table 1. Average contributions are plotted by subject type in Figure 7. Table 1: Summary Statistics for the Amounts Contributed Mean Median Mode Std. Dev. N Treatment type type Treatment type type Treatment 3 (type 3) Aggregate Figure 7: Average Contributions by Type Contribution Type The mean contribution in Treatment 1 is 2.80 and the median is 2. Type 1 subjects contributed an average of 2.04 compared to 2.95 for type 5 subjects. A Wilcoxon 16

17 ranksum test is suggestive that type 1 subjects contributed less than type 5 subjects (p = 0.12, see Table 3). This finding is consistent with Hypothesis 1, that contributions are increasing in a subject s type. The mean and median in Treatment 2 (5.03 and 5) are considerably higher than in Treatment 1. A Wilcoxon test provides strong evidence of a difference in contributions between the two treatments (p < 0.01, see Table 2). An explanation is that since there were two minority members in each group in Treatment 2, there was a potential for in-group reciprocity between minority members that did not exist in Treatment 1, where there was only one minority member in each group. Higher contributions by the minority group members may have positively affected the contributions of the majority group members. Type 2 subjects contributed an average of 3.42 compared to 5.84 for type 4 subjects. The contributions of type 2 subjects are not statistically different from those of type 1 (p = 0.16) or type 5 subjects (p = 0.74). In contrast, type 4 subjects contributed more than all other subject types (p < 0.01 for all pair-wise comparisons). The difference between type 2 and type 4 subjects is consistent with Hypothesis 1. Pair-wise comparisons between the contributions in Treatment 3 (mean = 2.10 and median = 2) and the contributions in Treatments 1 (p = 0.02) and 2 (p < 0.01) provide strong evidence that the contributions in Treatment 3 are the lowest of the three treatments. The type 3 subjects made contributions comparable to those of type 1 subjects (p = 0.83) and lower than those of type 2 (p = 0.05), type 4 (p < 0.01) and type 5 (p = 0.01) subjects. While the low contributions of type 3 subjects are unexpected given the potential for in-group reciprocity in Treatment 3, the lack of majority members may have caused a coordination failure where all subjects hoped the subjects from the other team would make high contributions. 17

18 Table 2: Pair-wise Comparisons of Contributions by Treatment Treatment Treatment Cells report the p-value of a Wilcoxon ranksum test. Table 3: Pair-wise Comparisons of Contributions by Type Type Type Cells report the p-value of a Wilcoxon ranksum test. Only one session of each treatment was conducted. As a result, comparisons between treatments and types may be confounded by session effects. In an effort to control for this, the average contribution of each subject type is divided by the average contribution in their session. The normalized average contributions are plotted in Figure 8. Figure 8: Normalized Average Contributions by Type Normalized Contribution Type 18

19 Minority members (type 1 and 2 subjects) contributed less than the average in their sessions and majority members (type 4 and 5 subjects) contributed more, consistent with the prediction of Hypothesis 1. Regressions determine how contributions are affected by subject type, repetition and beliefs. A random effects Tobit model preserves degrees of freedom and corrects for censoring. Contributions are regressed on the subject s type, the round number and beliefs about the contributions of in-group and out-group members as follows: contribution ir = β o + β t type + β r round + β in belief in + β out belief out + ε ir (2) where contribution ir is the contribution of subject i in round r, type is their type, round is the round number, belief in is the subject s belief about the average contribution of their in-group members in that round, belief out is their belief about the average contribution of their out-group members and ε ir is the error term. The 24 observations from type 1 subjects are omitted because type 1 subjects had no in-group beliefs. The regression results are reported in Table 4. 19

20 Table 4: Regressions of Contributions Coefficients Variables (1) (2) type 0.98*** - (0.18) type (0.59) type4-2.26*** (0.62) type5-2.71*** (0.67) round -0.08* (0.05) -0.09* (0.05) belief in 0.99*** (0.07) 0.95*** (0.10) belief out 0.26*** 0.30*** (0.10) constant -6.45*** (0.98) N ***: Significant at 1% **: Significant at 5% *: Significant at 10% (0.11) -4.19*** (0.98) Specification (1) uses the variable type to capture the subject s type. Specification (2) replaces the variable type with a set of dummy variables (type3, type4 and type5) and uses type 2 subjects as the reference group. The coefficient for the variable type (0.98) in specification (1) is highly significant and suggests that each unit increase in type is associated with an increase in contributions of This finding strongly supports Hypothesis 1. In specification (2), the coefficient for the variable type3 (0.85) indicates that type 3 subjects contributed 0.85 more than type 2 subjects. However, this finding is not statistically significant. In contrast, the coefficients for the variables type4 (2.26) and type5 (2.71) are highly significant and suggest that type 4 and 5 subjects contributed 2.26 and 2.71 more than type 2 subjects. The coefficients for the dummy variables are all consistent with Hypothesis 1. 20

21 The coefficients for the variable round (-0.08 and -0.09) are significant at 10% and suggest that contributions decrease by almost 0.10 in each round. Decreasing contributions are consistent with previous results in the literature. 5 The coefficients for the variable belief in (0.99 and 0.95) are significant at 1% and reflect an approximately oneto-one relationship between contributions and beliefs about the average contributions of in-group members. The coefficients for the variable belief out (0.26 and 0.30) are also significant at 1%, but are smaller in magnitude than the coefficients for the variable belief in (p < 0.01 in both specifications). The belief coefficients support Hypothesis 2, that contributions are increasing in a subject s in-group belief, and to a lesser degree, in their out-group belief. The negative regression constants (-6.45 and -4.19) indicate that there may be non-linear relationships between the variables of interest that are not captured by the linear specifications. Separate regressions for each subject type examine whether the effects of repetition and beliefs differ across subject types. The results are reported in Table 5. Table 5: Regressions of Contributions by Type Coefficients Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) round -0.51* (0.30) 0.27** (0.11) -0.18* (0.09) -0.20* (0.10) (0.08) belief in *** (0.17) 0.52*** (0.18) 1.26*** (0.15) 1.06*** (0.16) belief out *** (0.66) (0.21) (0.22) (0.21) constant *** * (4.08) (2.07) (1.33) (1.59) N ***: Significant at 1% **: Significant at 5% *: Significant at 10% (0.14) (1.12) Regression (1) uses the observations from type 1 subjects. The coefficient for the 5 See Ledyard (1995) for a survey. 21

22 variable round (-0.51) is significant at 10% and suggests that contributions decrease by 0.51 in each round. Type 1 subjects had no in-group members in their group and therefore had no beliefs about the contributions of such subjects. The coefficient for the variable belief out (-0.37) suggests that contributions decrease by 0.37 for every unit increase in the belief about the average contribution of out-group members. However, the effect is not statistically significant. Regression (2) indicates that type 2 subjects behaved differently from type 1 subjects. The coefficient for the variable round (0.27) is significant at 5% and suggests that contributions increase by 0.27 in each round. The coefficients for the variables belief in (1.06) and belief out (1.31) are highly significant and suggest approximately one-to-one relationships between contributions and beliefs about the average contributions of ingroup and out-group members. The finding that in-group beliefs have a smaller effect on contributions than out-group beliefs is unexpected, but is unique to type 2 subjects. The negative constant (-10.01) is indicative of non-linearities. Regression (3) finds a small, negative effect of repetition for type 3 subjects, suggesting that contributions decrease with repetition. The coefficient for the variable belief in (0.52) is positive and highly significant while the coefficient for the variable belief out (0.34) is positive, but not statistically significant. Like regression (3), regressions (4) and (5) find small, negative repetition effects, positive and highly significant effects of in-group beliefs and insignificant effects of out-group beliefs. The results regarding the effects of beliefs are generally consistent with Hypothesis 2. We now consider the determination of beliefs. Beliefs about the average contribution of in-group members are regressed on the subject s type, the round and lagged variables in a random effects Tobit model as follows: 22

23 belief in = β o + β t type + β r round + β act act 1 + β acot acot 1 +β c contribution 1 + β p payoff 1 + ε ir (3) where act 1 is the average amount contributed by group members of the subject s current type in the previous round, acot 1 is the average amount contributed by group members of the type other than the subject s current type in the previous round, contribution 1 is the subject s contribution in the previous round and payoff 1 was their payoff. 6 The results are given in Table 6. Table 6: Regression of In-group Beliefs Variable Coefficient type 1.02*** (0.13) round -0.22*** (0.03) act *** (0.09) acot (0.05) contribution (0.06) payoff (0.08) constant 1.16 (1.11) N 374 ***: Significant at 1% **: Significant at 5% *: Significant at 10% The coefficient for the variable type (1.02) is highly significant and suggests that each unit increase in type is associated with an increase in belief in of This result 6 Recall that subjects knew act 1 and acot 1 because they were informed of the average contributions of their in-group and out-group members at the end of each round. 23

24 indicates that subjects had in-group beliefs consistent with Hypothesis 1. The coefficient for the variable round (-0.22) is significant at 1% and suggests that in-group beliefs decrease by 0.22 in each round. The coefficients for the variables act 1 (0.35) and acot 1 (0.08) indicate that in-group beliefs are positively affected by the average contribution of group members of the subject s current type in the previous round, but not by the average contribution of group members of the type other than the subject s current type. This finding suggests that subjects believed in-group members would conform to social norms and contribute amounts similar to the amounts previously contributed by other subjects of the same type. The variables contribution 1 and payoff 1 do not have significant effects. Beliefs about the average contributions of out-group members are regressed on the same explanatory variables as the beliefs about the average contributions of in-group members and the estimates are presented in Table 7. Table 7: Regression of Out-group Beliefs Variable Coefficient type -0.50*** (0.07) round -0.14*** (0.03) act (0.08) acot *** (0.05) contribution * (0.06) payoff (0.07) constant 4.54*** (0.99) N 396 ***: Significant at 1% **: Significant at 5% *: Significant at 10% 24

25 The coefficient for the variable type (-0.50) is highly significant and suggests that a one unit increase in type (and a one unit decrease in the type of the subject s outgroup members) is associated with a decrease in belief out of This indicates that subjects had out-group beliefs consistent with Hypothesis 1. The coefficient for the variable round (-0.14) is significant at 1% and suggests that out-group beliefs decrease by 0.14 in each round. The coefficient for the variable act 1 (0.02) is not significant, but the coefficient for the variable acot 1 (0.17) suggests that subjects believed out-group members would make contributions increasing in the amounts previously contributed by other subjects of the same type. 5 Conclusions In this paper, we examined how group composition affects cooperation in a repeated VCM linear public good game. Identity was induced using a team-building activity and subjects were assigned to groups consisting of a varying number of subjects from each team. In addition to making contribution decisions, subjects revealed their beliefs about the contributions of the other subjects in their group from their team and from the other team. A primary finding was that minority members contributed less than majority members. Even when controlling for beliefs, subjects made contributions increasing in the number of subjects in their group from their team. This result supports the hypothesis that altruistic preferences are a function of identity. A second key finding was that contributions were increasing in beliefs about the contributions of other group members. However, beliefs about the contributions of group members from the same team had a larger effect on contributions than beliefs about the contributions of group members from the other team. This suggests that 25

26 while both types of reciprocity have important effects, in-group reciprocity is a stronger determinant of behaviour than out-group reciprocity, consistent with the hypothesis motivated by identity and reciprocity. A final issue is the formation of beliefs. The analysis of beliefs indicates that subjects expected others to make contributions consistent with the hypothesis of identity-based altruism. In addition, they also expected subjects to make contributions similar to the amounts previously contributed by subjects of the same type. One interpretation is that subjects thought others would conform to social norms and contribute the amount typical for their type. The results have important implications for social policy. To begin, for people to cooperate in their community they must feel as though they are part of the in-group. Disenfranchised individuals do not have the same incentives for cooperation and this will reduce their participation in the provision of public goods. Also, insofar as beliefs about the actions of others determine behaviour, it is the choices of similar individuals influencing the decisions people make. Campaigns aimed at increasing community involvement should promote the actions of citizens with whom most people identify. For example, it is unsatisfactory to use advertising depicting white families to attempt to reduce gang violence in predominantly black neighbourhoods. Possibilities for future research include the use of larger groups allowing for more variation in group composition. It seems this might produce additional interesting results. For example, a group of ten subjects consisting of a nine member majority might maintain high cooperation because they are undeterred by the free-riding of the lone minority member. This would be different from the analogous treatment in this experiment, where the five member majorities appeared dissuaded by the low contributions of single member minorities. 26

27 References Akerlof, G. and R. Kranton (2000). Economics and Identity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), Alesina, A., Baqir, R. and W. Easterly (1999). Public Goods and Ethnic Divisions. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(4), Alesina, A. and E. La Ferrara (2000). Participation in Heterogeneous Communities. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), Anderson, L., Mellor, J. and J. Milyo (2008). Inequality and Public Good Provision: An Experimental Analysis. Journal of Socio-Economics, 37(3), Andreoni, J. (1995). Cooperation in Public Goods Experiments: Kindness or Confusion? American Economic Review, 85(4), Andreoni, J. (1988). Why Free Ride? Strategies and Learning in Public Goods Experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 37(3), Andreoni, J. and J. Miller (1993). Rational Cooperation in the Finitely Repeated Prisoner s Dilemma: Experimental Evidence. Economic Journal, 103(418), Buckley, E. and R. Croson (2006). Income and Wealth Heterogeneity in the Voluntary Provision of Linear Public Goods. Journal of Public Economics, 90(4), Castro, M. (2006). Where are you from? Cultural Differences in Public Good Experiments. University of London Discussion Paper Chan, K., Mestelman, S., Moir, S. and A. Muller (1999). Heterogeneity and the Voluntary Provision of Public Goods. Experimental Economics, 2(1), Chan, K., Mestelman, S., Moir, S. and A. Muller (1996). The Voluntary Provision of Public Goods under Varying Income Distributions. Canadian Journal of Economics, 29(1), Chen, Y. and S. Li (forthcoming). Group Identity and Social Preferences. Amer- 27

28 ican Economic Review. Cherry, T., Kroll, S. and J. Shogren (2005). The Impact of Endowment Heterogeneity and Origin on Public Good Contributions: Evidence from the Lab. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 57(3), Cooper, R., DeJong, D., Forsythe, R. and T. Ross (1996). Cooperation without Reputation: Experimental Evidence from Prisoner s Dilemma Games. Games and Economic Behavior, 12(2), Croson, R. (2007). Theories of Commitment, Altruism and Reciprocity: Evidence from Linear Public Good Games. Economic Inquiry, 45(2), Dufwenberg, M. and G. Kirchsteiger (2004). A Theory of Sequential Reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 47(2), Dufwenberg, M., Gachter, S. and H. Hennig-Schmidt (2008). The Framing of Games and the Psychology of Play. University of Arizona Working Paper. Eckel, C. and P. Grossman (2005). Managing Diversity by Creating Team Identity. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 58(3), Fehr, E. and S. Gachter (2000). Cooperation and Punishment in Public Goods Experiments. American Economic Review, 90(4), Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-tree: Zurich Toolbox for Ready-made Economic Experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), Fischbacher, U., Gachter, S. and E. Fehr (2001). Are People Conditionally Cooperative? Evidence from a Public Goods Experiment. Economic Letters, 71(3), Fischbacher, U. and S. Gachter (2006). Heterogeneous Social Preferences and the Dynamics of Free Riding in Public Goods. CeDex Discussion Paper Fisher, J., Isaac, R., Schatzberg, J. and M. Walker (1995). Heterogeneous Demand for Public Goods: Behavior in the Voluntary Contributions Mechanism. Public 28

29 Choice, 85(3), Glaeser, E., Laibson, D. and B. Sacerdote (2002). An Economic Approach to Social Capital. Economic Journal, 112(483), Isaac, R., Walker, J. and S. Thomas (1984). Divergent Evidence on Free Riding: An Experimental Examination of Some Possible Explanations. Public Choice, 43(2), Knack S. and P. Keefer (1997). Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff? A Cross-Country Investigation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), Ledyard, J. (1995). Public Goods Experiments. In J. Kagel and A. Roth, Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ. Oxoby, R. and J. Spraggon (2006). A Clear and Present Minority: Heterogeneity in the Source of Endowments and the Provision of Public Goods. University of Calgary Discussion Paper Putnam, R. (2000). Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. Simon & Schuster, New York, NY. McLeish, K. and R. Oxoby (2007). Identity, Cooperation, and Punishment. University of Calgary Working Paper. Rabin, M. (1993). Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics. American Economic Review, 83(5), Ruffle, B. and R. Sosis (2006). Cooperation and the In-group-Out-group Bias: A Field Test on Israeli Kibbutz Members and City Residents. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 60(2), Simpson, B. (2006). Social Identity and Cooperation in Social Dilemmas. Rationality and Society, 18(4), Zak, P. and S. Knack (2001). Trust and Growth. Economic Journal, 111(470),

Contributions and Beliefs in Liner Public Goods Experiment: Difference between Partners and Strangers Design

Contributions and Beliefs in Liner Public Goods Experiment: Difference between Partners and Strangers Design Working Paper Contributions and Beliefs in Liner Public Goods Experiment: Difference between Partners and Strangers Design Tsuyoshi Nihonsugi 1, 2 1 Research Fellow of the Japan Society for the Promotion

More information

The Voluntary Provision of a Public Good with Binding Multi-Round Commitments

The Voluntary Provision of a Public Good with Binding Multi-Round Commitments September 28, 2005 The Voluntary Provision of a Public Good with Binding Multi-Round Commitments Matthew A. Halloran Department of Economics, Kansas State University, Waters Hall 339A, Manhattan, KS 66506,

More information

Sequential Decision and Strategy Vector Methods in Ultimatum Bargaining: Evidence on the Strength of Other- Regarding Behavior

Sequential Decision and Strategy Vector Methods in Ultimatum Bargaining: Evidence on the Strength of Other- Regarding Behavior Department of Economics Discussion Paper 2004-04 Sequential Decision and Strategy Vector Methods in Ultimatum Bargaining: Evidence on the Strength of Other- Regarding Behavior Robert J. Oxoby University

More information

Conditional Cooperation in Network Public Goods Experiments

Conditional Cooperation in Network Public Goods Experiments Conditional Cooperation in Network Public Goods Experiments Luke A. Boosey a a Department of Economics, Florida State University, 288 Bellamy Building, Tallahassee FL, 32306-2180, USA. Abstract This paper

More information

Theoretical Explanations of Treatment Effects in Voluntary Contributions Experiments

Theoretical Explanations of Treatment Effects in Voluntary Contributions Experiments Theoretical Explanations of Treatment Effects in Voluntary Contributions Experiments Charles A. Holt and Susan K. Laury * November 1997 Introduction Public goods experiments are notable in that they produce

More information

THE ROLE OF EXPECTATIONS IN THE PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS UNDER THE INFLUENCE OF SOCIAL IDENTITY

THE ROLE OF EXPECTATIONS IN THE PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS UNDER THE INFLUENCE OF SOCIAL IDENTITY Number 201 March 2014 THE ROLE OF EXPECTATIONS IN THE PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS UNDER THE INFLUENCE OF SOCIAL IDENTITY Matthias Lankau, Marianna Bicskei, Kilian Bizer ISSN: 1439-2305 THE ROLE OF EXPECTATIONS

More information

Endowment Effects and Contribution Strategies in Public Good Experiments

Endowment Effects and Contribution Strategies in Public Good Experiments Cadigan J. et al. Archives of Psychology, vol. 1, issue 1, October 2017 Page 1 of 17 REVIEW ARTICLE Endowment Effects and Contribution Strategies in Public Good Experiments John Weis 1, John Cadigan 2*,

More information

ExpEc I. Preliminaries

ExpEc I. Preliminaries ExpEc I. Preliminaries Giovanni Ponti Università di Ferrara Facoltà di Giurisprudenza LUISS Guido Carli LAboratory for Theoretical and EXperimental Economics Universidad de Alicante Roma, 7/6/2010 h t

More information

Cooperation and Collective Action

Cooperation and Collective Action Cooperation and Collective Action A basic design Determinants of voluntary cooperation Marginal private benefits Group size Communication Why do people cooperate? Strategic cooperation Cooperation as a

More information

DIFFERENCES IN THE ECONOMIC DECISIONS OF MEN AND WOMEN: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE*

DIFFERENCES IN THE ECONOMIC DECISIONS OF MEN AND WOMEN: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE* DIFFERENCES IN THE ECONOMIC DECISIONS OF MEN AND WOMEN: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE* Catherine C. Eckel Department of Economics Virginia Tech Blacksburg, VA 24061-0316 Philip J. Grossman Department of Economics

More information

Revisiting Kindness and Confusion in Public Goods Experiments

Revisiting Kindness and Confusion in Public Goods Experiments Revisiting Kindness and Confusion in Public Goods Experiments By DANIEL HOUSER AND ROBERT KURZBAN* There has been substantial recent interest in determining why there is cooperation in public goods experiments

More information

The Effect of Rewards and Sanctions in Provision of Public Goods

The Effect of Rewards and Sanctions in Provision of Public Goods CAEPR Working Paper #2006-005 The Effect of Rewards and Sanctions in Provision of Public Goods Martin Sefton University of Nottingham Robert Shupp Ball State University James Walker Indiana University

More information

Does Strategic Play Explain the Decay in Contributions in a Public Goods Game? Experimental Evidence

Does Strategic Play Explain the Decay in Contributions in a Public Goods Game? Experimental Evidence Does Strategic Play Explain the Decay in Contributions in a Public Goods Game? Experimental Evidence Ananish Chaudhuri Department of Economics University of Auckland a.chaudhuri@auckland.ac.nz Tirnud Paichayontvijit

More information

Inequity and Risk Aversion. in Sequential Public Good Games

Inequity and Risk Aversion. in Sequential Public Good Games Inequity and Risk Aversion in Sequential Public Good Games Sabrina Teyssier INRA-ALISS, 65 boulevard de Brandebourg, 94205 Ivry-sur-Seine Cedex, France. Email: Sabrina.Teyssier@ivry.inra.fr. September

More information

Trust and Cooperation: An experimental study*

Trust and Cooperation: An experimental study* Trust and Cooperation: An experimental study* Jeongbin Kim, Louis Putterman, and Xinyi Zhang November, 2016 Abstract: We use a two-phase experimental design to study one mechanism through which high trusting

More information

Conditional behavior affects the level of evolved cooperation in public good games

Conditional behavior affects the level of evolved cooperation in public good games Center for the Study of Institutional Diversity CSID Working Paper Series #CSID-2013-007 Conditional behavior affects the level of evolved cooperation in public good games Marco A. Janssen Arizona State

More information

Leadership with Individual Rewards and Punishments

Leadership with Individual Rewards and Punishments MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Leadership with Individual Rewards and Punishments Özgür Gürerk and Thomas Lauer and Martin Scheuermann RWTH Aachen University, University of Cologne 17. July 2015 Online

More information

Today s lecture. A thought experiment. Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness. Overview readings: Fehr and Fischbacher (2002) Sobel (2005)

Today s lecture. A thought experiment. Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness. Overview readings: Fehr and Fischbacher (2002) Sobel (2005) Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness Are we perfectly selfish? If not, does it affect economic analysis? How to take it into account? Overview readings: Fehr and Fischbacher (2002) Sobel (2005) Today

More information

The Behavioural Consequences of Unfair Punishment

The Behavioural Consequences of Unfair Punishment Department of Economics The Behavioural Consequences of Unfair Punishment Department of Economics Discussion Paper 10-34 Michalis Drouvelis The behavioural consequences of unfair punishment Michalis Drouvelis,

More information

Conditional Cooperation in Network Public Goods Experiments

Conditional Cooperation in Network Public Goods Experiments Conditional Cooperation in Network Public Goods Experiments Luke A. Boosey Abstract This study investigates the pattern of contribution decisions in a network public goods game. In this game, each player

More information

Altruism and Voluntary Provision of Public Goods. Leanne Ma, Katerina Sherstyuk, Malcolm Dowling and Oliver Hill ab

Altruism and Voluntary Provision of Public Goods. Leanne Ma, Katerina Sherstyuk, Malcolm Dowling and Oliver Hill ab Altruism and Voluntary Provision of Public Goods by Leanne Ma, Katerina Sherstyuk, Malcolm Dowling and Oliver Hill ab Abstract We study how people's predisposition towards altruism, as measured by tools

More information

Public Goods Provision and Sanctioning. in Privileged Groups

Public Goods Provision and Sanctioning. in Privileged Groups Public Goods Provision and Sanctioning in Privileged Groups Ernesto Reuben and Arno Riedl Abstract In public-good provision, privileged groups enjoy the advantage that some of their members find it optimal

More information

Contributions to public goods are often found to be conditional on the willingness of others to

Contributions to public goods are often found to be conditional on the willingness of others to Conditional Cooperation and Cultural Worldviews Todd Cherry, David M. McEvoy, and Håkon Sælen Published in Economics Letters 158, pp. 51-53. 1. Introduction Contributions to public goods are often found

More information

Cooperation and Public Goods Provision

Cooperation and Public Goods Provision Cooperation and Public Goods Provision A basic design Determinants of voluntary cooperation Marginal private benefits Group size Communication Why do people cooperate? Strategic cooperation Cooperation

More information

Supporting Information

Supporting Information Supporting Information Burton-Chellew and West 10.1073/pnas.1210960110 SI Results Fig. S4 A and B shows the percentage of free riders and cooperators over time for each treatment. Although Fig. S4A shows

More information

Koji Kotani International University of Japan. Abstract

Koji Kotani International University of Japan. Abstract Further investigations of framing effects on cooperative choices in a provision point mechanism Koji Kotani International University of Japan Shunsuke Managi Yokohama National University Kenta Tanaka Yokohama

More information

Partners versus Strangers: Random Rematching in Public Goods Experiments

Partners versus Strangers: Random Rematching in Public Goods Experiments Partners versus Strangers: Random Rematching in Public Goods Experiments by James Andreoni Department of Economics University of Wisconsin-Madison Madison, Wisconsin 53711 and Rachel Croson Wharton School

More information

The Game Prisoners Really Play: Preference Elicitation and the Impact of Communication

The Game Prisoners Really Play: Preference Elicitation and the Impact of Communication The Game Prisoners Really Play: Preference Elicitation and the Impact of Communication Michael Kosfeld University of Zurich Ernst Fehr University of Zurich October 10, 2003 Unfinished version: Please do

More information

Jakub Steiner The University of Edinburgh. Abstract

Jakub Steiner The University of Edinburgh. Abstract A trace of anger is enough: on the enforcement of social norms Jakub Steiner The University of Edinburgh Abstract It is well documented that the possibility of punishing free-riders increases contributions

More information

Social Comparisons and Pro-social Behavior: Testing Conditional Cooperation in a Field Experiment

Social Comparisons and Pro-social Behavior: Testing Conditional Cooperation in a Field Experiment Social Comparisons and Pro-social Behavior: Testing Conditional Cooperation in a Field Experiment By BRUNO S. FREY AND STEPHAN MEIER* Many important activities, such as charitable giving, voting, and paying

More information

Playing with the Good Guys: A Public Good Game with Endogenous Group Formation

Playing with the Good Guys: A Public Good Game with Endogenous Group Formation Playing with the Good Guys: A Public Good Game with Endogenous Group Formation Kjell Arne Brekke, Karen E. Hauge, Jo Thori Lind, Karine Nyborg Abstract In social dilemmas, conditional cooperators may be

More information

Tilburg University. Publication date: Link to publication

Tilburg University. Publication date: Link to publication Tilburg University Leading by Example? Investment Decisions in a Mixed Sequential-Simultaneous Public Bad Experiment van der Heijden, Eline; Moxnes, E. Publication date: 2003 Link to publication Citation

More information

AN EXPERIMENTAL ANALYSIS OF CONDITIONAL COOPERATION* Rachel Croson, Enrique Fatas and Tibor Neugebauer**

AN EXPERIMENTAL ANALYSIS OF CONDITIONAL COOPERATION* Rachel Croson, Enrique Fatas and Tibor Neugebauer** AN EXPERIMENTAL ANALYSIS OF CONDITIONAL COOPERATION* Rachel Croson, Enrique Fatas and Tibor Neugebauer** WP-AD 2006-24 Correspondence: Rachel Croson. The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 567

More information

Private vs. Public Strategies in a Voluntary Contributions Mechanism

Private vs. Public Strategies in a Voluntary Contributions Mechanism Private vs. Public Strategies in a Voluntary Contributions Mechanism November 10, 2010 Abstract Can more information on others strategies increase voluntary contributions to public goods? This paper addresses

More information

Giving To Ingrates?*

Giving To Ingrates?* Giving To Ingrates?* Michael Jones, Bridgewater State College and Michael McKee, Appalachian State University and University of Calgary February 2008 Michael Jones, Department of Economics, Bridgewater

More information

Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness

Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness Are we perfectly selfish and self-centered? If not, does it affect economic analysis? How to take it into account? Focus: Descriptive analysis Examples Will monitoring

More information

social preferences P000153

social preferences P000153 P000153 Behaviour in a variety of games is inconsistent with the traditional formulation of egoistic decision-makers; however, the observed differences are often systematic and robust. In many cases, people

More information

Using Cognitive Dissonance to Manipulate Social Preferences

Using Cognitive Dissonance to Manipulate Social Preferences DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 8310 Using Cognitive Dissonance to Manipulate Social Preferences Robert J. Oxoby Alexander Smith July 2014 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the

More information

Strong Reciprocity and Human Sociality

Strong Reciprocity and Human Sociality Notes on Behavioral Economics 1 Strong Reciprocity and Human Sociality Human groups are highly social despite a low level of relatedness. There is an empirically identifiable form of prosocial behavior

More information

Transparency and cooperation in repeated dilemma games: a meta study

Transparency and cooperation in repeated dilemma games: a meta study Exp Econ (2017) 20:755 771 DOI 10.1007/s10683-017-9517-4 ORIGINAL PAPER Transparency and cooperation in repeated dilemma games: a meta study Lenka Fiala 1 Sigrid Suetens 1 Received: 3 November 2015 / Revised:

More information

The weak side of informal social control Paper prepared for Conference Game Theory and Society. ETH Zürich, July 27-30, 2011

The weak side of informal social control Paper prepared for Conference Game Theory and Society. ETH Zürich, July 27-30, 2011 The weak side of informal social control Paper prepared for Conference Game Theory and Society. ETH Zürich, July 27-30, 2011 Andreas Flache Department of Sociology ICS University of Groningen Collective

More information

A Note On the Design of Experiments Involving Public Goods

A Note On the Design of Experiments Involving Public Goods University of Colorado From the SelectedWorks of PHILIP E GRAVES 2009 A Note On the Design of Experiments Involving Public Goods PHILIP E GRAVES, University of Colorado at Boulder Available at: https://works.bepress.com/philip_graves/40/

More information

A cash effect in ultimatum game experiments

A cash effect in ultimatum game experiments A cash effect in ultimatum game experiments JUNYI SHEN * Research Institute for Economics & Business Administration, Kobe University, Japan and HIROMASA TAKAHASHI Faculty of International Studies, Hiroshima

More information

Voluntary Participation and Spite in Public Good Provision Experiments: An International Comparison

Voluntary Participation and Spite in Public Good Provision Experiments: An International Comparison Experimental Economics, 5:133 153 (2002) c 2002 Economic Science Association Voluntary Participation and Spite in Public Good Provision Experiments: An International Comparison TIMOTHY N. CASON Department

More information

Generalized trust and prosocial behavior

Generalized trust and prosocial behavior Generalized trust and prosocial behavior Regina Kühne June 11, 2012 This is a DRAFT. Please do not quote or cite. Comments are very welcome (Email to regina.kuehne@wiwi.hu-berlin.de) Abstract There is

More information

Supplementary Information Appendix for: Prenatal Sex Hormones (2D:4D Digit Ratio) and Social Integration

Supplementary Information Appendix for: Prenatal Sex Hormones (2D:4D Digit Ratio) and Social Integration Supplementary Information Appendix for: Prenatal Sex Hormones (2D:4D Digit Ratio) and Social Integration Jaromír Kovářík*, Pablo Brañas-Garza**, Michael W. Davidson, Dotan A. Haim, Shannon Carcelli, and

More information

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION 1. Online recruitment procedure using Amazon Mechanical Turk... 2 2. Log-transforming decision times... 3 3. Study 1: Correlational decision time experiment on AMT... 4 4. Studies

More information

Passionate Providers and the Possibility of Public Commitment

Passionate Providers and the Possibility of Public Commitment 1 Passionate Providers and the Possibility of Public Commitment Luke A. Boosey, R. Mark Isaac, and Douglas A. Norton Department of Economics, Florida State University 288 Bellamy Building, Tallahassee

More information

Using Experimental Methods to Understand Why and How We Give to Charity By Lise Vesterlund

Using Experimental Methods to Understand Why and How We Give to Charity By Lise Vesterlund Using Experimental Methods to Understand Why and How We Give to Charity By Lise Vesterlund 1. Introduction 2. Preferences for Giving 2.1. Is Giving Rational? 2.2. Motives 2.2.1. Altruism, Warm-glow, or

More information

Group Size and Sincere Communication in Experimental Social Dilemmas

Group Size and Sincere Communication in Experimental Social Dilemmas Group Size and Sincere Communication in Experimental Social Dilemmas Mark Lubell a,b,*, Vicken Hillis b, William M. Baum a, Richard McElreath b,c, & Peter J. Richerson a,b a Environmental Science and Policy,

More information

How to identify trust and reciprocity

How to identify trust and reciprocity Games and Economic Behavior 46 (2004) 260 281 www.elsevier.com/locate/geb How to identify trust and reciprocity JamesC.Cox Department of Economics, 401 McClelland Hall, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ

More information

How Much Should We Trust the World Values Survey Trust Question?

How Much Should We Trust the World Values Survey Trust Question? How Much Should We Trust the World Values Survey Trust Question? Noel D. Johnson * Department of Economics George Mason University Alexandra Mislin Kogod School of Business, American University Abstract

More information

Altruism. Why Are Organisms Ever Altruistic? Kin Selection. Reciprocal Altruism. Costly Signaling. Group Selection?

Altruism. Why Are Organisms Ever Altruistic? Kin Selection. Reciprocal Altruism. Costly Signaling. Group Selection? Altruism Nepotism Common-Pool Resource (CPR) Tragedy of the Commons Public Good Free-riders Competitive Altruism A 1987 Florida news story reported that 22 blood donors who had false positives on an HIV

More information

Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game

Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game Ivaylo Vlaev (ivaylo.vlaev@psy.ox.ac.uk) Department of Experimental Psychology, University of Oxford, Oxford, OX1

More information

Author's personal copy

Author's personal copy Exp Econ DOI 10.1007/s10683-015-9466-8 ORIGINAL PAPER The effects of endowment size and strategy method on third party punishment Jillian Jordan 1 Katherine McAuliffe 1,2 David Rand 1,3,4 Received: 19

More information

Social Preferences of Young Adults in Japan: The Roles of Age and Gender

Social Preferences of Young Adults in Japan: The Roles of Age and Gender Social Preferences of Young Adults in Japan: The Roles of Age and Gender Akihiro Kawase Faculty of Economics, Toyo University, Japan November 26, 2014 E-mail address: kawase@toyo.jp Postal address: Faculty

More information

When in Rome: Conformity and the Provision of Public Goods. Jeffrey Carpenter. April, 2002 MIDDLEBURY COLLEGE ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER NO.

When in Rome: Conformity and the Provision of Public Goods. Jeffrey Carpenter. April, 2002 MIDDLEBURY COLLEGE ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER NO. When in Rome: Conformity and the Provision of Public Goods by Jeffrey Carpenter April, 2002 MIDDLEBURY COLLEGE ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 02-17 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MIDDLEBURY COLLEGE MIDDLEBURY,

More information

Do Control Questions Influence Behavior in Experiments?

Do Control Questions Influence Behavior in Experiments? Do Control Questions Influence Behavior in Experiments? Catherine Roux and Christian Thöni March 2013 Abstract Outcomes and strategies shown in control questions prior to experimental play may provide

More information

Fairness and Reciprocity in the Hawk-Dove game

Fairness and Reciprocity in the Hawk-Dove game Fairness and Reciprocity in the Hawk-Dove game Tibor Neugebauer*, Anders Poulsen**, and Arthur Schram*** Abstract We study fairness and reciprocity in a Hawk-Dove game. This allows us to test various models

More information

Cooperation, Trust, and Economic Development: An Experimental Study in China

Cooperation, Trust, and Economic Development: An Experimental Study in China Cooperation, Trust, and Economic Development: An Experimental Study in China JUNYI SHEN * Research Institute for Economics & Business Administration, Kobe University, Japan and XIANGDONG QIN School of

More information

Competition for Trophies Triggers Male Generosity

Competition for Trophies Triggers Male Generosity Competition for Trophies Triggers Male Generosity Xiaofei (Sophia) Pan and Daniel Houser April 2011 Discussion Paper Interdisciplinary Center for Economic Science 4400 University Drive, MSN 1B2, Fairfax,

More information

Social Norms and Reciprocity*

Social Norms and Reciprocity* Social Norms and Reciprocity* Andreas Diekmann Institut für Soziologie Universität Bern Thomas Voss Institut für Soziologie Universität Leipzig [ March 2003 ] Paper presented on the session Solidarity

More information

Mini-Course in Behavioral Economics Leeat Yariv. Behavioral Economics - Course Outline

Mini-Course in Behavioral Economics Leeat Yariv. Behavioral Economics - Course Outline Mini-Course in Behavioral Economics Leeat Yariv The goal of this mini-course is to give an overview of the state of the art of behavioral economics. I hope to trigger some research in the field and will

More information

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION Supplementary Statistics and Results This file contains supplementary statistical information and a discussion of the interpretation of the belief effect on the basis of additional data. We also present

More information

Behavioral Game Theory

Behavioral Game Theory Outline (September 3, 2007) Outline (September 3, 2007) Introduction Outline (September 3, 2007) Introduction Examples of laboratory experiments Outline (September 3, 2007) Introduction Examples of laboratory

More information

Color Cues and Viscosity in. Iterated Prisoner s Dilemma

Color Cues and Viscosity in. Iterated Prisoner s Dilemma Color Cues and Viscosity in Iterated Prisoner s Dilemma Michael Joya University of British Columbia Abstract The presence of color tag cues and a viscous environment have each been shown to foster conditional

More information

Cooperation under the threat of expulsion in a public goods experiment

Cooperation under the threat of expulsion in a public goods experiment Journal of Public Economics 89 (2005) 1421 1435 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Cooperation under the threat of expulsion in a public goods experiment Matthias Cinyabuguma, Talbot Page, Louis Putterman*

More information

Altruistic Behavior: Lessons from Neuroeconomics. Kei Yoshida Postdoctoral Research Fellow University of Tokyo Center for Philosophy (UTCP)

Altruistic Behavior: Lessons from Neuroeconomics. Kei Yoshida Postdoctoral Research Fellow University of Tokyo Center for Philosophy (UTCP) Altruistic Behavior: Lessons from Neuroeconomics Kei Yoshida Postdoctoral Research Fellow University of Tokyo Center for Philosophy (UTCP) Table of Contents 1. The Emergence of Neuroeconomics, or the Decline

More information

COOPERATION 1. How Economic Rewards Affect Cooperation Reconsidered. Dan R. Schley and John H. Kagel. The Ohio State University

COOPERATION 1. How Economic Rewards Affect Cooperation Reconsidered. Dan R. Schley and John H. Kagel. The Ohio State University COOPERATION 1 Running Head: COOPERATION How Economic Rewards Affect Cooperation Reconsidered Dan R. Schley and John H. Kagel The Ohio State University In Preparation Do Not Cite Address correspondence

More information

CeDEx Discussion Paper Series ISSN

CeDEx Discussion Paper Series ISSN Discussion Paper No. 2009 09 Daniele Nosenzo and Martin Sefton April 2009 Endogenous Move Structure and Voluntary Provision of Public Goods: Theory and Experiment CeDEx Discussion Paper Series ISSN 1749

More information

Area Conferences 2012

Area Conferences 2012 A joint initiative of Ludwig-Maximilians University s Center for Economic Studies and the Ifo Institute CESifo Conference Centre, Munich Area Conferences 2012 CESifo Area Conference on Behavioural Economics

More information

Communication, Advice and Beliefs in an Experimental Public Goods Game

Communication, Advice and Beliefs in an Experimental Public Goods Game Communication, Advice and Beliefs in an Experimental Public Goods Game Ananish Chaudhuri Department of Economics University of Auckland a.chaudhuri@auckland.ac.nz Pushkar Maitra Department of Economics

More information

Social Learning and Norms in a Public Goods Experiment with Intergenerational

Social Learning and Norms in a Public Goods Experiment with Intergenerational Social Learning and Norms in a Public Goods Experiment with Intergenerational Advice Ananish Chaudhuri Department of Economics University of Auckland a.chaudhuri@auckland.ac.nz Sara Graziano Charles River

More information

By Olivia Smith and Steven van de Put Third Year, Second Prize

By Olivia Smith and Steven van de Put Third Year, Second Prize Are humans always the rational, self-interested agents that mainstream economics assumes them to be? Discuss, using ideas of reciprocity, altruism and fairness By Olivia Smith and Steven van de Put Third

More information

Beauty, Gender and Stereotypes: Evidence from Laboratory Experiments

Beauty, Gender and Stereotypes: Evidence from Laboratory Experiments Beauty, Gender and Stereotypes: Evidence from Laboratory Experiments James Andreoni University of Wisconsin Madison, WI 53706 Ragan Petrie Georgia State University Atlanta, GA 30303 October 2005 Abstract

More information

Women and Men are Different but Equal: Observations of Learning Behavior in Auctions

Women and Men are Different but Equal: Observations of Learning Behavior in Auctions Women and Men are Different but Equal: Observations of Learning Behavior in Auctions Dinah Pura T. Depositario Associate Professor, University of the Philippines at Los Baños College, Laguna, 4031 Philippines

More information

Charitable Giving in the Laboratory: Advantages of the Piecewise Linear Public Goods Game

Charitable Giving in the Laboratory: Advantages of the Piecewise Linear Public Goods Game Charitable Giving in the Laboratory: Advantages of the Piecewise Linear Public Goods Game Michael Menietti, Harvard University María P. Recalde, University of Melbourne Lise Vesterlund, University of Pittsburgh

More information

VOLKSWIRTSCHAFTLICHE ABTEILUNG. Reputations and Fairness in Bargaining Experimental Evidence from a Repeated Ultimatum Game with Fixed Opponents

VOLKSWIRTSCHAFTLICHE ABTEILUNG. Reputations and Fairness in Bargaining Experimental Evidence from a Repeated Ultimatum Game with Fixed Opponents VOLKSWIRTSCHAFTLICHE ABTEILUNG Reputations and Fairness in Bargaining Experimental Evidence from a Repeated Ultimatum Game with Fixed Opponents Tilman Slembeck March 999 Discussion paper no. 99 DEPARTMENT

More information

Do Race and Fairness Matter in Generosity? Evidence from a Nationally Representative Charity Experiment

Do Race and Fairness Matter in Generosity? Evidence from a Nationally Representative Charity Experiment Do Race and Fairness Matter in Generosity? Evidence from a Nationally Representative Charity Experiment The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits

More information

Heinrich H. Naxa, Ryan O. Murphya, Kurt A. Ackermann Interactive preferences

Heinrich H. Naxa, Ryan O. Murphya, Kurt A. Ackermann Interactive preferences Heinrich H. Naxa, Ryan O. Murphya, Kurt A. Ackermann Interactive preferences Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Nax, Heinrich H., Murphy, Ryan O. and Ackermann, Kurt A. (2015) Interactive

More information

3/30/11 Bosses and Kings: Asymmetric Power in Paired Common Pool and Public Good Games* 2011 by authors

3/30/11 Bosses and Kings: Asymmetric Power in Paired Common Pool and Public Good Games* 2011 by authors 3/30/11 Bosses and Kings: Asymmetric Power in Paired Common Pool and Public Good Games* James C. Cox, 1 Elinor Ostrom, 2 and James M. Walker 3 2011 by authors Abstract: Social dilemmas characterize decision

More information

Accepting Zero in the Ultimatum Game Does Not Reflect Selfish. preferences

Accepting Zero in the Ultimatum Game Does Not Reflect Selfish. preferences Accepting Zero in the Ultimatum Game Does Not Reflect Selfish Preferences Gianandrea Staffiero a, Filippos Exadaktylos b* & Antonio M. Espín c a. Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Spain. Department of Economics

More information

Measuring Identity. February 12, Abstract

Measuring Identity. February 12, Abstract Measuring Identity Yan Chen Xin (Sherry) Li February 12, 2006 Abstract Identity is a central concept in the social sciences. We present a laboratory experiment that measures the effects of induced group

More information

Simultaneous Decision-Making in Competitive and Cooperative Environments

Simultaneous Decision-Making in Competitive and Cooperative Environments MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Simultaneous Decision-Making in Competitive and Cooperative Environments Anya Savikhin and Roman Sheremeta 5. March 2012 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/46809/

More information

Discussion of Trust or Reciprocity? The Effect of Controls on Other-Regarding Behavior

Discussion of Trust or Reciprocity? The Effect of Controls on Other-Regarding Behavior Discussion of Trust or Reciprocity? The Effect of Controls on Other-Regarding Behavior Discussion by Nicole Cade and Sarah McVay Bridging the gap Controls Controls are any action a firm takes to influence

More information

Institutionalize reciprocity to overcome the public goods. provision problem

Institutionalize reciprocity to overcome the public goods. provision problem WINPEC Working Paper Series No.E1509 July 2015 Institutionalize reciprocity to overcome the public goods provision problem Hiroki Ozono, Yoshio Kamijo, and Kazumi Shimizu Waseda INstitute of Political

More information

Journal of Public Economics

Journal of Public Economics Journal of Public Economics 114 (2014) 19 28 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Public Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jpube Loopholes undermine donation: An experiment

More information

Irrationality in Game Theory

Irrationality in Game Theory Irrationality in Game Theory Yamin Htun Dec 9, 2005 Abstract The concepts in game theory have been evolving in such a way that existing theories are recasted to apply to problems that previously appeared

More information

Unaffected Strangers Affect Contributions

Unaffected Strangers Affect Contributions Nordic Journal of Political Economy Volume 32 26 Pages 93-112 Unaffected Strangers Affect Contributions Mari Rege Kjetil Telle This article can be dowloaded from: http://www.nopecjournal.org/nopec_26_a5.pdf

More information

UC Merced Proceedings of the Annual Meeting of the Cognitive Science Society

UC Merced Proceedings of the Annual Meeting of the Cognitive Science Society UC Merced Proceedings of the Annual Meeting of the Cognitive Science Society Title Fairness overrides reputation: The importance of fairness considerations in altruistic cooperation Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/8wp9d7v0

More information

A Competitive Approach to Leadership in Public Good Games

A Competitive Approach to Leadership in Public Good Games A Competitive Approach to Leadership in Public Good Games Samuele Centorrino a, Laura Concina b a Corresponding author. Toulouse School of Economics and GREMAQ, Manufacture des Tabacs, 21 Allée de Brienne,

More information

Emanuela Carbonara. 31 January University of Bologna - Department of Economics

Emanuela Carbonara. 31 January University of Bologna - Department of Economics Game Theory, Behavior and The Law - I A brief introduction to game theory. Rules of the game and equilibrium concepts. Behavioral Games: Ultimatum and Dictator Games. Entitlement and Framing effects. Emanuela

More information

Is Reciprocity Really Outcome-Based? A Second Look at Gift-Exchange with Random Shocks

Is Reciprocity Really Outcome-Based? A Second Look at Gift-Exchange with Random Shocks Is Reciprocity Really Outcome-Based? A Second Look at Gift-Exchange with Random Shocks Brent J. Davis, Rudolf Kerschbamer, and Regine Oexl October 30, 2017 Abstract By means of a laboratory experiment,

More information

Giving, taking, and gender in dictator games

Giving, taking, and gender in dictator games CBESS Discussion Paper 14-09 Giving, taking, and gender in dictator games by Subhasish M. Chowdhury*, Joo Young Jeon*, and Bibhas Saha** * School of Economics, University of East Anglia ** Economics in

More information

EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS INTRODUCTION. Ernesto Reuben

EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS INTRODUCTION. Ernesto Reuben EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS INTRODUCTION Ernesto Reuben WHAT IS EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS? 2 WHAT IS AN ECONOMICS EXPERIMENT? A method of collecting data in controlled environments with the purpose of furthering

More information

Social Status and Group Norms: Indirect Reciprocity in a Helping Experiment

Social Status and Group Norms: Indirect Reciprocity in a Helping Experiment Social Status and Group Norms: Indirect Reciprocity in a Helping Experiment Ingrid Seinen and Arthur Schram CREED Department of Economics and Econometrics University of Amsterdam Roetersstraat 11 1018

More information

WHY SOCIAL PREFERENCES MATTER THE IMPACT OF NON-SELFISH MOTIVES ON COMPETITION, COOPERATION AND INCENTIVES

WHY SOCIAL PREFERENCES MATTER THE IMPACT OF NON-SELFISH MOTIVES ON COMPETITION, COOPERATION AND INCENTIVES The Economic Journal, 112 (March), C1 C33.. Published by Blackwell Publishers, 108 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 1JF, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA. WHY SOCIAL PREFERENCES MATTER THE IMPACT OF

More information

DO WEALTH DIFFERENCES AFFECT FAIRNESS CONSIDERATIONS?

DO WEALTH DIFFERENCES AFFECT FAIRNESS CONSIDERATIONS? DO WEALTH DIFFERENCES AFFECT FAIRNESS CONSIDERATIONS? Olivier Armantier May 2003 Abstract The influence of relative wealth on fairness considerations is analyzed in a series of ultimatum game experiments

More information