Compatibility and the Use of Information Processing Strategies

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Compatibility and the Use of Information Processing Strategies"

Transcription

1 Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, Vol. 11, (1998) Compatibility and the Use of Information Processing Strategies MARCUS SELART,!' TOMMY GARLING,! AND HENRY MONTGOMERY^! Goteborg University, Sweden ^Stockholm University, Sweden ABSTRACT When a prominent looms larger in one response procedure than in another, a violation of procedure invariance occurs. A hypothesis based on compatibility between the structure of the input information and the required output was tested as an explanation of this phenomenon. It was also compared with other existing hypotheses in the field. The study had two aims: (1) to illustrate the prominence effect in a selection of preference tasks (choice, acceptance decisions, and preference ratings); (2) to demonstrate the processing differences in a matching procedure versus the selected preference tasks. Hence, verbal protocols were collected in both a matching task and in subsequent preference tasks. Silent control conditions were also employed. The structure compatibility hypothesis was confirmed in that a prominence effect obtained in the preference tasks was accompanied by a lower degree of attention to the levels in these tasks. Furthermore, as predicted from the structure compatibility hypothesis, it was found that fewer comparisons between levels were performed in the preference tasks than in the matching task. It was therefore concluded that both these processing differences may explain the occurrence of the prominence effects John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 11: 59-72, KEY WORDS: compatibility; preference elicitation; prominence effect; information structure; verbal protocols INTRODUCTION One of the key priticiples of normative decision theory is that rational decision makers express their preferences in an invariant way. Thus, the use of different procedures to elicit preferences should not Correspondence to: Marcus Selart, Goteborg University. Department of Psychology, Haraldsgatan 1, S Goteborg, Sweden Contract grant sponsors: Swedish Council for Research in the Humanities and Social Sciences, Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences CCC /98/ $17.50 Received 2 July John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Accepted 14 July 1997

2 60 Journal of Behavioral Decision Making Vol. 11, Iss. No. I influence the responses (Kahneman and Tversky, 1984). Nevertheless, procedure invariance is often violated by preference reversals, occurring in both risky and riskless situations (e.g. Slovic, Griffin, and Tversky, 1990; Slovic and Lichtenstein, 1983; Tversky, Sattath, and Slovic, 1988; Tversky, Slovic, and Kahneman, 1990; see Payne, Bettman, and Johnson, 1992, and Slovic, 1995, for reviews). Preference reversals were first demonstrated for gambles (Lichtenstein and Slovic, 1971, 1973; see also Slovic and Lichtenstein, 1983). It was shown that subjects in choosing generally prefer gamble alternatives with large probabilities of winning small amounts. However, in pricing subjects state a higher cash equivalent of gambles with small chances of winning large amounts. The phenomenon has also been demonstrated in riskless multi situations (Slovic et al., 1990; Tversky et al., 1988). For instance, it has been shown that subjects in choice tasks involving two options and two s place more weight on the prominent or most important than what they do in a judgmental matching task. Tversky et al. (1988) argued that this latter phenomenon, which was labelled the prominence effect, occurs because choice and matching tasks evoke different types of decision strategies which place different weight on the prominent. It was suggested that different tasks invoke different kinds of reasoning. Fischer and Hawkins (1993) furthermore proposed that not only matching judgments but judgments in general require quantitative reasoning, whereas choices are characterized by qualitative comparison. The qualitative response in choice was regarded as compatible with a lexicographic decision rule which renders quantitative weighting of s unnecessary. In contrast, quantitative judgments were seen as compatible with a quantitative weighting rule. In this way the response mode was considered as priming the focus of attention to the compatible features of the input. This form of compatibility has been referred to as strategy compatibility (Fischer and Hawkins, 1993; Hawkins, 1994; Stone and Schkade, 1991). Another related mechanism that may produce compatibility effects has been termed scale compatibility (Fischer and Hawkins, 1993; Tversky et al., 1988). Different judgmental response scales have been found to be more or less compatible with the s used to describe the items on the input side. For instance, Slovic et al. (1990) found that since a grading scale was more compatible with past grades than with past class ranks, the former was overweighed. In a similar vein, Schkade and Johnson (1989) showed that pricing judgments primed the attention to the winning amount, just like rating scales primed the attention to probabilities. In both cases the most attended to was overweighed. In line with this. Chapman and Johnson (1994) discovered that scale compatibility produces anchoring effects if the anchor and a preference judgment are expressed on the same scale. It was also shown by Chapman and Johnson (1995) that semantic categorization is an important feature of scale compatibility. For instance, in life expectancy evaluations, health items were preferred to commodities, whereas in monetary evaluations commodities were preferred to health items. In an overview of current compatibility theories, Shafir (1995) has recently discussed the scale and strategy compatibility hypotheses. The structure compatibility framework In addition to what should be expected from these accounts of the prominence effect, previous research has shown that a prominent looms larger also in preference ratings as compared to matching. In fact, it has been found that the prominence effect for preference ratings is equally robust and as uniform as the prominence effect in choice (Fischer and Hawkins, 1993; Montgomery et al., 1994; Selart, 1994, 1996; Selart et al., 1994). We therefore adopt another perspective on compatibility in this study. Instead of explaining the prominence effect with compatibility between qualitative or quantitative response modes and decision rule, we propose that the prominence effect is due to differences in compatibility between the structure of the input information and the required output. Structure Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, Vol. 11, (1998) 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

3 M. Selart, T. Garling and H. Montgomery Compatibility 61 compatibility is assumed to be optimal when the complexity in input and required output is at the same level (the same number of elements and relations between elements). For instance, consider a matching task which includes two treatment alternatives described by two s, pain relief and efficiency. The degrees of pain relief and efficiency are expressed on a scale ranging from 0 (no pain relief/efficiency) to 100 (full pain relief/efficiency). For one of the treatments one value is missing. For instance. Treatment A Treatment B Pain relief Efficiency 45? The subjects' task is to complete the missing value so that both treatments appear equally attractive. In this task, the required output may be regarded as a difference between two elements which is compared to an input which also consists of a difference between two elements. Irrespective of whether subjects match -wise or alternative-wise, the complexity in input and output is at the same level, implying that structure compatibility is optimal. However, in choice and preference rating the required output is less complex than the input. Thus, structure compatibihty is suboptimal. Consider, for example, a task involving two options and two s like in the former case. In choice, the required output then consists of a relationship between two elements (i.e. a preference ordering of two options), whereas the input consists of four elements (the levels for each option) between which there are various relationships. In preference rating the required output is simply one element (e.g. an attractiveness rating on a scale ranging from 1 to 100) and the input consists of two elements (the levels for the judged option). The structure compatibility in choice and preference ratings will therefore be at the same level if it is assumed that the subject bases his or her choice on attractiveness judgments of each option.. The structure compatibility hypothesis thus states that when the structure compatibility is suboptimal, the subject will anchor the required output to a subset of input elements which is at the same ^complexity level as the required output. As a consequence, these input elements will have a greater weight for the output as compared to the situation when the structure compatibility is optimal. Furthermore, we assume that as a rule the subject will anchor his or her choice or judgment on the more important due to its greater salience in relation to subject's current goals or interests. This reasoning can be related to the results of Schkade and Kleinmuntz (1994) which suggest that strategies are influenced by the organization of individual items of information into structures. They further suggest that organization strongly influences information acquisition, that is, acquisition is seen as influenced by alternative-wise or -wise stimulus presentation. We think that similar task demands in both choices and preference ratings (sub-optimal structure compatibility) manifest a common organization principle which is different from that used in matching. Differences between structure compatibility and the competing hypotheses It should be noted how our hypothesis differs from the other compatibility hypotheses. Both competing hypotheses (strategy compatibility, scale compatibility) restrict themselves to explain a task effect, that is, the implication of different response procedures. However, structure compatibility may also provide an explanation of other task effects and may also clarify context effects like the effect of similarity between alternatives (see Payne, 1982, and Payne, Bettman, and Johnson, 1993, for a review). Another difference is that the scale compatibility hypotheses stresses that compatibility will not affect the prominence effect/jer se but will only enhance the weight ofthe compatible, whereas a high 1998 John Wiley & Sons. Ltd. Journal of Behaviorai Decision Making, Vol (1998)

4 62 Journal of Behavioral Decision Making Vol. 11, Iss. No. 1 degree of structure compatibility will reduce the prominence effect. On the other hand strategy compatibility implies that only so-called qualitative compatibility (i.e. compatibility between a qualitative response mode and a qualitative decision strategy) will result in a prominence effect. According to both the competing hypotheses (strategy compatibility, scale compatibility) the prominence effect should not be general among preference tasks but should be limited to choice. The scale compatibility hypothesis (Tversky et al., 1988) predicts an absence ofthe prominence effect for preference ratings if the scales ofthe dimensions are made compatible with the output. For instance, in the present study the levels of each pair of alternatives range from 1 to 100 for both the prominent and the non-prominent as does the response scale in the rating task. According to the scale compatibility hypothesis, a more equal weighting of the s will hence take place in preference rating than in choice due to this manipulation. The strategy compatibility hypothesis (Fischer and Hawkins, 1993) also predicts a prominence effect in choice, since different kinds of reasoning are assumed to be inherent in choices and judgments independently of the information structure. For instance, a qualitative response mode will trigger a compatible decision strategy which in turn will enhance the prominence effect. As a consequence, both these competing hypotheses predict that there should not exist any processing differences between matching and preference rating which could be related to different degrees of structure compatibility. Predictions The objective of this study is to test the structure compatibility hypothesis. In line with previous findings we predict that prominence effects will occur in both choice and preference ratings in comparison to the matching task. We further test the hypothesis by examining the processing differences between matching, on the one hand, and choice and preference rating, on the other. The prediction is also made that a prominence effect will occur in acceptance decisions in comparison to the matching task, and hence the processing difference between this procedure and the matching task is investigated. The acceptance decisions are introduced in order to study the effects of a qualitative response mode in which the alternatives are evaluated one by one, like in the preference rating task. By introducing acceptance decisions it is hence possible to test the idea that evaluation order is of minor importance for the prominence effect in quahtative procedures (see Shafir, 1993, for a discussion). According to the structure compatibility hypothesis subjects in the preference tasks will tend to use non-compensatory lexicographic evaluation strategies (i.e. base their response primarily on' the prominent ), whereas in matching tasks subjects will use compensatory evaluation strategies with a more equal weighting of both the s. Of special relevance for the test ofthe hypothesis is therefore the degree of attention given to the levels in the matching task and in the subsequent preference tasks. This degree is measured by the number of subjects' statements in verbal protocols which are related to alternatives, s, or levels. In the present study, subjects match a number of two-dimensional medical treatments prior to evaluating these treatments using three different response modes. Three predictions are made concerning subjects' information processing. An optimal structure compatibihty implies that: (1) Subjects compare one difference with another in the matching task. They are therefore expected to pay more attention to the levels in this task than they are in the preference tasks. We therefore register how often they attend to the levels. (2) Subjects are expected to give an equal amount of attention to both s in the matching task. In contrast, the use of a lexicographic strategy in the preference tasks is expected to lead to a pronounced level of attention to the prominent. Hence, we register how much attention subjects are giving to the prominent and the non-prominent (Ford et al., 1989). Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, Vol. 11, (1998) 1998 John Wiley & Sons. Ltd.

5 M. Selart, T. Gdrling and H. Montgomery Compatibility 63 (3) Subjects will use the additive-weigh ting principle in the matching task. They are therefore expected to compare the levels (independently of whether the comparisons are made within or across s) in this task more often than they are in the preference tasks. The predictions of the structure compatibility hypothesis and of the other hypotheses are summarized in Exhibit 1. Exhibit 1. The different compatibility hypotheses and their predictions Hypothesis Type of effect Definition of compatibility Predictions Strategy compatibility Task Compatibility between a qualitative response modes and a qualitative decision strategy or between a quantitative response mode and a quantitative decision strategy Qualitative compatibility will result in a prominence effect. The effect is thus restricted to choice procedures. Scale compatibility Task Compatibility between a judgmental response scale and an used to describe the items on the input side Compatibility will enhance the weight of the compatible. The prominence effect will only occur in choice procedures. Structure compatibility Task and context Compatibility between the structure of the input information and the required output. Compatibility will decrease the prominence effect. The prominence effect is not restricted to choice procedures and may also occur in judgments like for instance preference ratings. Compatibility implies (i) a higher degree of attention to the levels, (ii) an equal attention to both the prominent and the nonprominent, and (iii) the use of a quantitative decision strategy. METHOD An approach devised by Slovic (1975) is used in which subjects first match two alternatives in order to make them equally attractive. Then they perform a preference task (choice, acceptance decision, or preference rating). In the latter tasks subjects thus evaluate their own matched alternatives. If subjects' preferences at this stage reliably depart from the chance level, for instance in that the prominent is overweighed, then a prominence effect is at hand. It may be questioned how it can be ruled out that the matching procedure in itself will not affect the outcome of the preference tasks. It should therefore be noted that we used the same stimulus material in an earlier study (Selart et al., 1994) using between-group comparisons. A replication of the generality of the prominence effect in the present study would thus indicate a robustness of the effect across the two types of designs. Verbal protocols are obtained in order to be able to study attention in the different tasks. To be able to test if the verbal protocols are reactive in the matching and the preference tasks (Russo, Johnson, and Stephens, 1989), half of the subjects are not given think-aloud instructions. The reason for using verbal protocols instead of, for instance, information boards is that verbal protocols provide rich naturalistic data which are needed for testing the predictions which are made. Furthermore, there is no indication of that verbal protocols would produce different results in terms of preferences than would information boards (e.g. Ford et al., 1989) John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, Vol. 11, (1998)

6 64 Journal of Behavioral Decision Making Vol. 11, Iss. No. 1 Subjects Seventy-two undergraduate students of psychology at Goteborg University served as subjects in return for financial compensation. Subjects were randomly assigned to six equal-sized groups. In three of these, subjects first performed a matching task followed by a preference task (choice, acceptance decision, or preference rating) while they were thinking aloud. In the other three conditions, the task requirements were the same but subjects were not prompted to think aloud. Procedure Eight problems were each presented twice to subjects in individually randomized orders which were repeated. Each problem consisted of two medical treatments which were described on two s. In pretests, one of the s had been observed to be more important. The values were expressed on a scale ranging from 1 to 100. Exhibit 2 displays the levels ofthe eight problems presented to subjects. Exhibit 2. Attribute levels of choice problems (medical treatments) presented to subjects Attribute Medicai car^ (1-100) Freedom from disturbance (1-100) Heatth improvement (1-100) Comfort (1-100) Efficiency {\-\00) Pain-relief (1-100) Medical skiii {\-\00) Freedom from fees (1-100) Food vaiue {\-\00) Size of food portions (1-100) Protection against relapse (1-100) Program shortage (1-100) Medicai foiiow-up (1-100) Freedom from encroachment (1-100) Communication with staff {X-XOXH) Leisure (1-100) "Prominent in italics. Option Option On each trial all subjects first performed a matching task. In each pair one value was missing and subjects' task was to supply a value which made the alternatives equally attractive, as exemplified by the following pair (as in the former example efficiency is the prominent and pain-relief the non-prominent ): Treatment 1 Treatment 2 Efficiency Pain-relief 46 A value was missing for one ofthe alternatives (either the prominent or non-prominent alternative in a counterbalanced order) the first time the problem was presented. Whether the value was missing on the prominent or non-prominent was counterbalanced for each subject across problems. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, Vol. 11, (1998) 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

7 M. Selart, T. Gdrling and H. Montgomery Compatibility 65 Immediately following the matching task, subjects performed the preference task. For different subjects it either consisted of a preference rating (subjects rated one of the options on a compatible scale ranging from 1 to 100), an acceptance decision of one ofthe options (subjects indicated whether or not they accepted the option), or a choice between two options. When subjects made preference ratings or acceptance decisions of an alternative in the pair, they were directed to evaluate one alternative the first time and the other alternative the second time in an order which for each subject was counterbalanced across problems. Half of the subjects were instructed to verbalize their thoughts during the completion of the tasks. If silent for more than approximately 10 seconds, they were reminded ofthe instructions and prompted to think aloud. The think-aloud reports were tape recorded and later transcribed. RESULTS Matching task. The analyses of the results rested on the assumption that "P.p + "P.np = "NP.p + "NP.np (1) where Wp p and Wp ^p denote the attractiveness of the levels of the prominent and non-prominent s for the prominent option (with the highest value on the prominent ) and Mf^,p and "NP.np t^^ corresponding attractiveness of the levels of the prominent and nonprominent s for the nonprominent option. The equality in equation (1) thus results from asking subjects to match the options. If the objective levels are denoted x and it is assumed that M, = w.x, with w. denoting the weights, then by substitution in equation (1): *Vp/**'np = (^NP,np-^P.np)/(^P.p " %P,p) (2) The data from the matching task were used to verify that one of the s was prominent. This was done by computing the ratio between the difference in values for the prominent and the difference in values for the non-prominent. As shown in Exhibit 3, this ratio is reliably higher than 1.0 as was expected (/? < 0.05). A 2 (think-aloud/silent condition) by 3 (preference task) analysis of variance (ANOVA) yielded no significant main or interaction effects at/? = Exhibit 3. Mean ratios rating task condition Think-aloud condition Silent condition of weights for prominent and non-prominent s in the matching task by choice/ Choice Acceptance decision Preference rating The prominence effect A measure ofthe strength ofthe prominence effect was calculated as follows. A score of 1 was assigned if subjects chose the prominent alternative and a score of 0 if they chose the non-prominent alternative. A score of 1 was similarly assigned if subjects judged the prominent alternative as acceptable and the non-prominent alternative as not acceptable, 0 if the reverse was the case. If both alternatives were judged as acceptable or not acceptable, a score of 0.5 was assigned. If subjects judged their preference to be higher for the prominent alternative, a score of 1 was assigned. If subjects judged their preference to be higher for the non-prominent alternative, a score of 0 was assigned. Ties in preferencejudgments were given a score of John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, Vol. 11, (1998)

8 66 Journal of Behavioral Decision Making Vol. 11, Iss. No. 1 Exihibit 4. Mean response seores for choice, acceptance decision, and preference rating Response mode Choice Acceptance decision Preference rating Think-aloud condition Silent condition In Exhibit 4 the strength of the prominence effect is shown in the six different conditions. In case thai: there is not a prominence effect, these numbers would all be Consistent with previous results (Montgomery et ai, 1994; Selart et al, 1994), a prominence effect was obtained in each condition. In a 2 (think aloud/silent condition) by 3 (preference task) ANOVA, no significant main or interaction effects were revealed aip Nevertheless, the main effect of type of preference task was close to significant {p < 0.10), suggesting that the prominence effect was marginally stronger in choice than in the other two conditions. The response scores were reliably different from 0.50 in all conditions {p < 0.001). Think-aloud reports The processing of the think-aloud reports followed the procedure developed in previous research (e.g. Harte, Westenberg, and van Someren, 1994; Montgomery and Svenson, 1989; Svenson, 1989). Briefly, the coding of the protocols was subdivided into two phases, that is, the division of the protocols into statements (e.g. a sentence with one main idea) and the assignment of categories to each statement. Subsequently, each statement was coded with respect to (1) which of the options, if any, it referred to, (2) which of the s, if any, it referred to, and (3) whether subjects compared both options or made an evaluation of a single option. The reliability was determined to be satisfactory for a randomly chosen 10% of all statements coded by an additional judge. For each subject, attention was calculated by aggregating all statements which referred to the levels. Each statement which referred to a single level received a score of 1. If a statement reflected a comparison between two levels, each of the compared levels received a score of 1. All cases of possible comparisons between the four types of levels were coded in this respect. The results are given in Exhibit 5. As revealed by a 2 (matching task/preference task) by 3 (preference task) by 2 (alternative) by 2 () by 2 (comparison/single attention) ANOVA with repeated measures on the last three factors, more levels were attended to in the matching task than in the preference tasks, a finding which was in line with the hypothesis, F{1, 33) = 16.89, p < Furthermore, it was more usual that levels were compared than attended to singly, F(l,33) = 7.89, p <0.0l. This tendency was more pronounced in the matching task than in the preference tasks, F{1, 33) = 6.82, p <0.0\. The interaction between matching task/preference task and failed however to reach significance, suggesting that the prominent was not reliably more attended to than the nonprominent, F{\, 33) 0.91,p = However, a reliable interaction between alternative and showed that there was a difference in attention to the s within the prominent alternative in favor of the prominent, F(l,33) = 10.93, p < This difference was observed in almost all conditions. - To further substantiate that subjects compare the levels more in the matching task than in the preference tasks, an index was created based on the proportions of the levels compared - and the levels which were attended singly. The difference between the frequency of levels compared and levels attended to singly was divided by the total amount of levels compared and levels attended to singly. For all instances in which the total amount Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, Vol. 11, (1998) 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

9 M. Selart, T. Gdrling and H. Montgomery Exhibit 5. Mean attention to levels in the think-aloud condition Prominent option Compatibility 67 Non-prominent option Prominent Non-prominent Prominent Non-prominent Choice condition Matching task Attribute levels compared Attribute levels attended singly Preference task Attribute levels compared Attribute levels attended singly Acceptance decision condition Matching task Attribute levels compared Attribute levels attended singly Preference task Attribute levels compared Attribute levels attended singly Preference rating condition Matching task Attribute levels compared Attribute levels attended singly Preference task Attribute levels compared Attribute levels attended singly equalled 0, mean values for each term were used as replacements, in order to save cases in the analysis (division with 0 would delete cases). This recoding procedure included about 35% of all data. The missing data hence consisted of statements made by subjects in which no explicit reference was made to the levels. It did therefore not indicate silence. The means of the proportions are presented in Exhibit 6. As was shown by a 2 (matching task/preference task) by 3 (preference task) by 2 (alternative) Exhibit 6. Mean index of attention to attibute levels in the think-aloud condition Prominent option Non-prominent option Prominent Non-prominent Prominent Non-prominent Choice condition Matching task Preference task Acceptance decision condition Matching task Preference task Preference rating condition Matching task Preference task 0.76" "Positive numbers indicate that subjects predominantly compared the levels, negative numbers that they predominantly attended to the levels singly John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, Vol. 11, (1998)

10 68 Journal of Behavioral Decision Making Vol. 11, Iss. No. I by 2 () ANOVA, the proportions of compared levels were higher in the matching task than in the preference tasks, F{\, 33) = 10.97, /? < A reliable interaction with preference task revealed that this tendency was most profound in the choice condition, F{2, 33) = 6.44, p < Furthermore, it was found that the proportion of compared levels was higher for the prominent than for the non-prominent, F(l, 33) = 8.68,/? < This effect was once again strongest in the choice condition, F{2, 33) = 5.24, p < In addition, it was found that the proportion of compared levels was higher for the prominent option in choice, but lower for the same option in preference rating, F{2, 33) 6.63, p < It was also observed that the proportion of compared levels was higher for the prominent of the non-prominent option than for the prominent of the prominent option, F{1, 33) = 60.55, p < This tendency was most evident in the preference rating condition. DISCUSSION A method devised by Slovic (1975) was used in which subjects matched two alternatives in order to make them equally attractive prior to performing a preference task (choice, acceptance decision, or preference rating). Verbal protocols were collected in the experimental condition, but not in the control condition. A prominence effect was obtained for choices. This finding replicated the results of Tversky et al. (1988) who demonstrated the effect using a between-subjects design entailing choice and matching. In addition, prominence effects for acceptance decisions and preference ratings were also observed in the present study. We used a silent control condition in order to test the confounding effects of giving verbal protocols (Russo, Johnson, and Stephens, 1989). The response scores in this condition did not depart from those in the think-aloud condition, indicating that a prominence effect was obtained in both conditions. Consequently, it was suggested that the verbal protocols did not cause any reactivity in this respect. It was hypothesized that the prominence effect may be explained by assuming that the preference tasks are characterized by a suboptimal structure compatibility. In these tasks a complete set of levels were presented in contrast to the initial matching task. However, the preference tasks were heterogeneous in the sense that two of them were qualitative (choice, acceptance decision) whereas one was quantitative in nature (preference rating). Despite this, no reliable differences in the strength of the prominence effect were obtained. The results obtained cannot be explained by strategy or scale compatibility. In strategy compatibility the distinction between qualitative and quantitative response modes is highlighted (Fischer and. Hawkins, 1993; Tversky et al., 1988). This principle explains why the most important looms larger in choice than in matching, with reference to the qualitative/quantitative distinction. Apparently., the prominence effect obtained for preference ratings cannot be explained by this principle. Scale compatibility implies that the input is weighted more heavily if it is expressed on the same scale as the response (Tversky et al., 1988). Our levels ranged from 1 to 100 for both the prominent and the non-prominent, as did our response scale for preference ratings. According to the scale compatibility principle, this should have resulted in a more equal weighting of the s in preference rating than in the choice and acceptance tasks. The verbal protocols showed that the prominence effect was accompanied by a lower degree of attention to the levels in the preference tasks than in the matching task. Subjects also less frequently compared levels in the preference tasks than in the matching task. The results were thus in line with the predictions from the structure compatibility hypothesis. However, the enhanced attention to the prominent that should have been found in the preference tasks, reflecting a lexicographic decision strategy, was not observed. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, Vol. 11, (1998) 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

11 M. Selart, T. Gdrling and H. Montgomery Compatibility 69 An important issue is therefore what can be concluded about subjects' use of decision strategies from the processing data. Our prediction was that a compensatory strategy (the additive weighting rule) should be used in the matching task, while a non-compensatory strategy (the lexicographic rule) should be used in the preference tasks. To be able to perform the matching task, subjects must make trade-offs along dimensions, and thus it seems reasonable to assume that a compensatory strategy had to be used. In line with this, our data revealed that the information processing of the matching task was based on more information and included more comparisons between the levels. These are typical signs of compensatory strategies. The generality of the prominence effect among the preference tasks indicated that a lexicographic strategy was used in these tasks. Hence, subjects rank ordered the dimensions and systematically preferred the option with the highest value on the most important. However, as revealed by the processing data, the use of this strategy did not imply that more attention was given to the prominent in comparison to the non-prominent. Nevertheless, the obtained prominence effect across the preference tasks and the observed lower degrees of attention to the levels in these response modes, confirm the structure-compatibility hypothesis (Montgomery et al., 1994; Selart et al., 1994; Selart, 1996). The observed process differences also provide an account of how the principle functions at a cognitive level. Although there were no differences to be observed between the mean weight ratios of the matching task among conditions, minor differences could be observed on the process level of the matching task among conditions in terms of the attention given to the levels (see Exhibits 5 and 6). This indicates that subjects in the matching task are more sensitive to different conditions in their processing of the information than in their elicitation of the weights. There have been several studies dealing with partly the same issues as have been raised in the present study. Recently, such a study was conducted by Hawkins (1994). He introduced a set of hypotheses of which a majority concerned processing differences (response time, fixation time) between choice and matching. A computerized information board technique was used in the empirical investigation. First, the prominence effect was replicated. It was also revealed that the matching task in relation to choice had (1) longer total response times, (2) more acquisitions, and (3) longer relative fixations time for the prominent. Furthermore, it was found that a prominence effect between choice and matching could be d to relative attention to the prominent in choice. These results show clear similarities with those obtained in our verbal protocol analysis which also focused on the choicematching discrepancy. However, in addition to these results our model accounts for similar processing differences observed between matching and preference rating. By technical reasons, we have nevertheless only been able to confirm longer total response times and more acquisitions in the matching task, and have not been able to corroborate longer relative fixations times spent on the prominent. Our results may also be related to those obtained by Schkade and Kleinmuntz (1994). They emphasized the role of information structure on preference elicitation. It was revealed that the acquisition of information is influenced by how the stimulus is presented. For instance, it was shown to be crucial whether the levels were presented -wise or alternative-wise. The importance of information structure was also noted by Payne et al. (1992). As in the present study, they investigated the contingency of preferences on task demands. Subjects were asked to make comparisons between input data, before they were instructed to elicit their preferences in a subsequent task. Examples of such comparisons were information transformations (e.g. rounding off, standardizing, or performing calculations), rearranging information (e.g. changing the order of the options or s), or eliminating information (see also Russo, 1977; Ranyard, 1989). It was found that subjects engaged in these comparison tasks prior to the preference elicitation task were to a higher extent using alternativebased strategies when processing the restructured material John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, \o\. 11, 59-72(1998)

12 70 Journal of Behavioral Decision Making Vol. 11, Iss. No. 1 Another related account was presented by Payne (1982). He suggested that two general classes of variables play a major part for how subjects construct their preferences. These are the task and the context effects. Task effects can be related to manipulations of the general structure of the decision, including response mode, number of options or s, time pressure, and presentation constraints. Context effects, on the other hand, can be connected to manipulations of the content of the decision problem, involving values, similarity of alternatives, covariation, and overall attractiveness of alternatives. It seems important to clarify that although structure compatibility effects in this study are due to manipulations of the task, this type of compatibility has also been demonstrated to be inherent in context effects. For instance, it has been found that the manipulation of different value ranges between the levels infiuence the magnitude of the prominence effect (Selart, 1996). In summary, our results suggest a contingent weighting mechanism. As indicated by the generality of the prominence effect, supported by a lower degree of attention to the levels, especially in terms of performed comparisons, these results provide a clear support for a structure compatibility explanation. The hypothesis is also supported by a higher proportion of compared levels of the prominent than of the non-prominent. Taking previous research into account, it must be pointed out that features like scale type, semantic characteristics, and information structure may all produce overweighing phenomena, like the prominence effect. It might be argued that to be able to study the effect of information presentation in a broader sense, different ways of presenting the information should be compared while using the same evaluation task. Despite the fact that such an analysis was not performed in this study, it seems clear that the notion of structure compatibility provides an account at a more specific level of how the construction of preferences may depend on information presentation. It is also important to note that other variables like positive versus negative comparisons between the levels might also have explanatory value for the prominence effect. AUTHORS' NOTE The study was financially supported by grants to the first author from the Swedish Council for Research in the Humanities and Social Sciences and from the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences. A previous version of the paper was presented at the 7th conference of the European Society for Cognitive Psychology (ESCOP), Lisbon, Portugal, in September We thank Harma Savioja-Jensen for assistance in the documentation and analysis of the verbal protocols. REFERENCES Chapman, G. B. and Johnson, E. J. 'The limits of anchoring'. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 7 (1994), Chapman, G. B. and Johnson, E. J. 'Preference reversals in monetary and life expectancy evaluations', Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 62 (1995), Fischer, G. W. and Hawkins, S. A. 'Strategy compatibility, scale compatibility, and the prominence effect'. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 19 (1993), Ford, J. K., Schmitt, N., Schechtman, S. L., Hults, B. M. and Doherty, M. L. 'Process tracing methods: Contributions, problems, and neglected research issues'. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 43 (1989), Harte, J. M., Westenberg, M. R. M. and van Someren, M. 'Process models of decision making', Acta Psycho- /og/ca, 87(1994), Hawkins, S. A. 'Information processing strategies in riskless preference reversals: The prominence effect', Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 59 (1994), Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. 'Choices, values, and frames'. The American Psychologist, 39 (1984), Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, Vol. 11, (1998) 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

13 M. Selart, T. Gdrling and H. Montgomery Compatibility 71 Lichtenstein, S. and Slovic, P. 'Reversals of preference between bids and choices in gambling decisions'. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 89 (1971), Lichtenstein, S. and Slovic, P. 'Response-induced reversals of preference in gambling: An extended replication in Las Vegas', Journal of Experimental Psychology, 101 (1973), Montgomery, H., Selart, M., Garling, T. and Lindberg, E. 'The judgment-choice discrepancy: Noncompatibility or restructuring?' Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 7 (1994), Montgomery, H. and Svenson, O. 'A think-aloud study of dominance structuring in decision processes'. In Montgomery, H. and Svenson, O. (eds). Process and Structure in Human Decision Making, Chichester: Wiley, Payne, J. W. 'Contingent decision behavior'. Psychological Bulletin, 92 (1982), Payne, J. W., Bettman, J. R., Coupey, E. and Johnson, E. J. 'A constructive process view of decision making: Multiple strategies in judgment and choice', Acta Psychologica, 80 (1992), Payne, J. W., Bettman, J. R. and Johnson, E. J. 'Behavioral decision research: A constructive processing perspective'. Annual Review of Psychology, 43 (1992), Ranyard, R. 'Structuring and evaluating simple monetary risks', in Montgomery, H. and Svenson, O. (eds). Process and Structure in Human Decision Making, Chichester: Wiley, Russo, J. E. 'The value of unit price information'. Journal of Marketing Research, 14 (1977), Russo, J. E., Johnson, E. J. and Stephens, D. L. 'The validity of verbal protocols'. Memory & Cognition, 17 (1989), Schkade, D. A. and Johnson, E. J. 'Cognitive processes in preference reversals'. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 44 (1989), Schkade, D. A. and Kleinmuntz, D. N. 'Information displays and choice processes: Differential effects of organization, form and sequence'. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 57 (1994), Selart, M. Preference Reversals in Judgment and Choice: The Prominence Effect, Doctoral dissertation, Goteborg University, Sweden, Selart, M. 'Structure compatibility and restructuring in judgment and choice'. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 65 (1996), Selart, M., Montgomery, H., Romanus, J. and Garling, T. 'Violations of procedure invariance in preference measurement: Cognitive explanation', European Joural of Cognitive Psychology, 6 (1994), Shafir, E. 'Choosing versus rejecting: Why some options are both better and worse than others'. Memory & Cognition, 21 (1993), Shafir, E. 'Compatibility in cognition and decision', in Busemeyer, J., Hastie, R. and Medin, D. L. (eds). Decision Making from a Cognitive Perspective. The Psychology of Learning and Motivation, Vol.32 (pp ), San Diego: Academic Press, Slovic, P. 'Choice between equally valued alternatives'. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 1 (1975), Slovic, P. 'The construction of preference', American Psychologist, 50 (1995), Slovic, P., Griffin, D. and Tversky, A. 'Compatibility effects in judgment and choice', in Hogarth, R. M. (ed.). Insights in Decision Making: A Tribute to Hillel J. Einhorn (pp. 5-27), Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, Slovic, P. and Lichtenstein, S. 'Preference reversals: A broader perspective', American Economic Review, 73 (1983), Stone, D. N. and Schkade, D. A. 'Numeric and linguistic information representation in multi choice'. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 49 (1991), Svenson, O. 'Eliciting and analysing verbal protocols in process studies of judgment and decision making', Montgomery, H. and Svenson, O. (eds). Process and Structure in Human Decision Making. Chichester: Wiley, Tversky, A., Sattath, S. and Slovic, P. 'Contingent weighting in judgment and choice'. Psychological Review, 95 (1988), Tversky, A., Slovic, P. and Kahneman, D. 'The causes for preference reversals'. The American Economic Review, 80(1990), ) 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, Vol. 11, (1998)

14 72 Journal of Behavioral Decision Making Vol. 11, Iss. No. I Authors' biographies: Marcus Selart is Assistant Professor of Psychology at Goteborg University. His research mainly concern various issues in behavioral decision making. Tommy Garling is Professor of Psychology at Goteborg University. His main research areas are behavioral decision making and environmental psychology. Henry Montgomery is Professor of Cognitive Psychology at Stockholm University. His current research deals with perspective shifts in evaluations of decision outcomes. Authors'addresses: Marcus Selart and Tommy Garling, Department of Psychology, Goteborg University, Haraldsgatan 1, S Goteborg, Sweden. Henry Montgomery, Department of Psychology, Stockholm University, S Stockholm, Sweden. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, Vol. 11, (1998) 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

15

The effect of decision frame and decision justification on risky choice

The effect of decision frame and decision justification on risky choice Japanese Psychological Research 1993, Vol.35, No.1, 36-40 Short Report The effect of decision frame and decision justification on risky choice KAZUHISA TAKEMURA1 Institute of Socio-Economic Planning, University

More information

Attention, Frame Condition and Decision Making Under Risk:

Attention, Frame Condition and Decision Making Under Risk: Attention, Frame Condition and Decision Making Under Risk: An Empirical Test of the Contingent Focus Model using an Eye Gaze Recorder Satoshi Fujii 1 & Kazuhisa Takemura 2 1 Tokyo Institute of Technology,

More information

Contingent Weighing of Past and Future Decision Outcomes

Contingent Weighing of Past and Future Decision Outcomes No. 5:31,1 Contingent Weighing of Past and Future Decision Outcomes Ásgeir Juliusson, Niklas Karlsson, and Tommy Gärling Department of Psychology Göteborg University Juliusson, Á, Karlsson, N., and Gärling,

More information

Effects of causal relatedness and uncertainty on integration of outcomes of concurrent decisions

Effects of causal relatedness and uncertainty on integration of outcomes of concurrent decisions Available online at www.sciencedirect.com ScienceDirect Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 190 ( 2015 ) 113 119 2nd GLOBAL CONFERENCE on PSYCHOLOGY RESEARCHES, 28-29, November 2014 Effects of causal

More information

Information Presentation Constraints and the Adaptive Decision Maker Hypothesis

Information Presentation Constraints and the Adaptive Decision Maker Hypothesis Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition 1, Vol. 25, No. 2,42-446 Copyright 1 by the American Psychological Association, Inc. 02-33//S3.00 Information Presentation Constraints

More information

UNESCO EOLSS. This article deals with risk-defusing behavior. It is argued that this forms a central part in decision processes.

UNESCO EOLSS. This article deals with risk-defusing behavior. It is argued that this forms a central part in decision processes. RISK-DEFUSING BEHAVIOR Oswald Huber University of Fribourg, Switzerland Keywords: cognitive bias, control, cost of risk-defusing operators, decision making, effect of risk-defusing operators, lottery,

More information

Choice set options affect the valuation of risky prospects

Choice set options affect the valuation of risky prospects Choice set options affect the valuation of risky prospects Stian Reimers (stian.reimers@warwick.ac.uk) Neil Stewart (neil.stewart@warwick.ac.uk) Nick Chater (nick.chater@warwick.ac.uk) Department of Psychology,

More information

Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game

Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game Ivaylo Vlaev (ivaylo.vlaev@psy.ox.ac.uk) Department of Experimental Psychology, University of Oxford, Oxford, OX1

More information

It is Whether You Win or Lose: The Importance of the Overall Probabilities of Winning or Losing in Risky Choice

It is Whether You Win or Lose: The Importance of the Overall Probabilities of Winning or Losing in Risky Choice The Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 30:1; 5 19, 2005 c 2005 Springer Science + Business Media, Inc. Manufactured in The Netherlands. It is Whether You Win or Lose: The Importance of the Overall Probabilities

More information

Exploring the reference point in prospect theory

Exploring the reference point in prospect theory 3 Exploring the reference point in prospect theory Gambles for length of life Exploring the reference point in prospect theory: Gambles for length of life. S.M.C. van Osch, W.B. van den Hout, A.M. Stiggelbout

More information

Intuitive Confidence and the Prominence Effect: When Consumer Choices are Sensitive to Matching Prices. Joseph P. Simmons Yale University

Intuitive Confidence and the Prominence Effect: When Consumer Choices are Sensitive to Matching Prices. Joseph P. Simmons Yale University 1 Intuitive Confidence and the Prominence Effect: When Consumer Choices are Sensitive to Matching Prices Joseph P. Simmons Yale University Leif D. Nelson New York University Joseph P. Simmons is Assistant

More information

Contingent focus model of Decision Framing under Risk Satoshi Fujii 1 & Kazuhisa Takemura 2. Tokyo Institute of Technology, Japan

Contingent focus model of Decision Framing under Risk Satoshi Fujii 1 & Kazuhisa Takemura 2. Tokyo Institute of Technology, Japan Technical Report 67, Department of Civil Engineering, Tokyo Institute of Technology, 51-67. Contingent focus model of Decision Framing under Risk Satoshi Fujii 1 & Kazuhisa Takemura 2 1 Tokyo Institute

More information

Comparative Ignorance and the Ellsberg Paradox

Comparative Ignorance and the Ellsberg Paradox The Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 22:2; 129 139, 2001 2001 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Manufactured in The Netherlands. Comparative Ignorance and the Ellsberg Paradox CLARE CHUA CHOW National University

More information

Framing the frame: How task goals determine the likelihood and direction of framing effects

Framing the frame: How task goals determine the likelihood and direction of framing effects McElroy, T., Seta, J. J. (2007). Framing the frame: How task goals determine the likelihood and direction of framing effects. Judgment and Decision Making, 2(4): 251-256. (Aug 2007) Published by the Society

More information

Appendix 1: Description of Selected Decision Processing Theories

Appendix 1: Description of Selected Decision Processing Theories Appendix 1: Description of Selected Decision Processing Theories The Behavioral Decision Framework (BDF) [1-4] describes the foundations of a model of a good decision-making process (for an early precursor

More information

PREFERENCE REVERSAL: A NEW LOOK AT AN OLD PROBLEM. SHU LI Institute of Psychology, Chinese Academy of Sciences, China Peking University, China

PREFERENCE REVERSAL: A NEW LOOK AT AN OLD PROBLEM. SHU LI Institute of Psychology, Chinese Academy of Sciences, China Peking University, China The Psychological Record, 2006, 56, 411-428 PREFERENCE REVERSAL: A NEW LOOK AT AN OLD PROBLEM SHU LI Institute of Psychology, Chinese Academy of Sciences, China Peking University, China A generalized weak

More information

Gamble Evaluation and Evoked Reference Sets: Why Adding a Small Loss to a Gamble Increases Its Attractiveness. Draft of August 20, 2016

Gamble Evaluation and Evoked Reference Sets: Why Adding a Small Loss to a Gamble Increases Its Attractiveness. Draft of August 20, 2016 Evoked Reference Sets -- 1 Gamble Evaluation and Evoked Reference Sets: Why Adding a Small Loss to a Gamble Increases Its Attractiveness Craig R. M. McKenzie UC San Diego Shlomi Sher Pomona College Draft

More information

Why Does Similarity Correlate With Inductive Strength?

Why Does Similarity Correlate With Inductive Strength? Why Does Similarity Correlate With Inductive Strength? Uri Hasson (uhasson@princeton.edu) Psychology Department, Princeton University Princeton, NJ 08540 USA Geoffrey P. Goodwin (ggoodwin@princeton.edu)

More information

Award Addresses. The Construction of Preference. Paul Slovic Decision Research and University of Oregon

Award Addresses. The Construction of Preference. Paul Slovic Decision Research and University of Oregon Award Addresses The Construction of Preference Paul Slovic Decision Research and University of Oregon One of the main themes that has emerged from behavioral decision research during the past 2 decades

More information

Understanding Consumer Usage of Product Magnitudes Through Sorting Tasks

Understanding Consumer Usage of Product Magnitudes Through Sorting Tasks Cornell University School of Hotel Administration The Scholarly Commons Articles and Chapters School of Hotel Administration Collection 12-1999 Understanding Consumer Usage of Product Magnitudes Through

More information

Risk attitude in decision making: A clash of three approaches

Risk attitude in decision making: A clash of three approaches Risk attitude in decision making: A clash of three approaches Eldad Yechiam (yeldad@tx.technion.ac.il) Faculty of Industrial Engineering and Management, Technion Israel Institute of Technology Haifa, 32000

More information

Implicit Information in Directionality of Verbal Probability Expressions

Implicit Information in Directionality of Verbal Probability Expressions Implicit Information in Directionality of Verbal Probability Expressions Hidehito Honda (hito@ky.hum.titech.ac.jp) Kimihiko Yamagishi (kimihiko@ky.hum.titech.ac.jp) Graduate School of Decision Science

More information

Department of Economics Working Paper Series

Department of Economics Working Paper Series Department of Economics Working Paper Series The Common Ratio Effect in Choice, Pricing, and Happiness Tasks by Mark Schneider Chapman University Mikhael Shor University of Connecticut Working Paper 2016-29

More information

Personal involvement, task complexity, and the decision making process: An information search analysis'

Personal involvement, task complexity, and the decision making process: An information search analysis' Japanese Psychological Rescarch 1994, Vol.36, No. 1. 41-48 Special lssue: Decision Making Personal involvement, task complexity, and the decision making process: An information search analysis' KAZUHISA

More information

Controlling the Information Flow: Effects on Consumers Decision Making and Preferences

Controlling the Information Flow: Effects on Consumers Decision Making and Preferences Controlling the Information Flow: Effects on Consumers Decision Making and Preferences Dan Ariely ABSTRACT One of the main objectives facing marketers is to present consumers with information on which

More information

Framing as Path Dependence Natalie Gold and Christian List 1

Framing as Path Dependence Natalie Gold and Christian List 1 1 Framing as Path Dependence Natalie Gold and Christian List 1 Forthcoming in Economics and Philosophy Revised on 30 March 2004 Abstract. A framing effect occurs when an agent s choices are not invariant

More information

Risky Choice Decisions from a Tri-Reference Point Perspective

Risky Choice Decisions from a Tri-Reference Point Perspective Academic Leadership Journal in Student Research Volume 4 Spring 2016 Article 4 2016 Risky Choice Decisions from a Tri-Reference Point Perspective Kevin L. Kenney Fort Hays State University Follow this

More information

Consider the following scenario: A consumer is deciding

Consider the following scenario: A consumer is deciding The Impact of Common Features on Consumer Preferences: A Case of Confirmatory Reasoning ALEXANDER CHERNEV* This article examines how confirmatory reasoning moderates the impact of attractive and unattractive

More information

The Influence of Hedonic versus Utilitarian Consumption Goals on the Compromise Effect. Abstract

The Influence of Hedonic versus Utilitarian Consumption Goals on the Compromise Effect. Abstract The Influence of Hedonic versus Utilitarian Consumption Goals on the Compromise Effect Abstract This article reports the effects of hedonic versus utilitarian consumption goals on consumers choices between

More information

Disjunction Effect in Prisoners Dilemma: Evidences from an Eye-tracking Study

Disjunction Effect in Prisoners Dilemma: Evidences from an Eye-tracking Study Disjunction Effect in Prisoners Dilemma: Evidences from an Eye-tracking Study Evgenia Hristova (ehristova@cogs.nbu.bg) Maurice Grinberg (mgrinberg@nbu.bg) Central and Eastern European Center for Cognitive

More information

How Different Choice Strategies Can Affect the Risk Elicitation Process

How Different Choice Strategies Can Affect the Risk Elicitation Process IAENG International Journal of Computer Science, 32:4, IJCS_32_4_13 How Different Choice Strategies Can Affect the Risk Elicitation Process Ari Riabacke, Mona Påhlman, Aron Larsson Abstract This paper

More information

INTERVIEWS II: THEORIES AND TECHNIQUES 5. CLINICAL APPROACH TO INTERVIEWING PART 1

INTERVIEWS II: THEORIES AND TECHNIQUES 5. CLINICAL APPROACH TO INTERVIEWING PART 1 INTERVIEWS II: THEORIES AND TECHNIQUES 5. CLINICAL APPROACH TO INTERVIEWING PART 1 5.1 Clinical Interviews: Background Information The clinical interview is a technique pioneered by Jean Piaget, in 1975,

More information

Decisions based on verbal probabilities: Decision bias or decision by belief sampling?

Decisions based on verbal probabilities: Decision bias or decision by belief sampling? Decisions based on verbal probabilities: Decision bias or decision by belief sampling? Hidehito Honda (hitohonda.02@gmail.com) Graduate School of Arts and Sciences, The University of Tokyo 3-8-1, Komaba,

More information

A Computational Model of Counterfactual Thinking: The Temporal Order Effect

A Computational Model of Counterfactual Thinking: The Temporal Order Effect A Computational Model of Counterfactual Thinking: The Temporal Order Effect Clare R. Walsh (cwalsh@tcd.ie) Psychology Department, University of Dublin, Trinity College, Dublin 2, Ireland Ruth M.J. Byrne

More information

PREFERENCE REVERSAL: AN EXPERIMENTAL INVESTIGATION OF ECONOMIC AND PSYCHOLOGICAL HYPOTHESES*

PREFERENCE REVERSAL: AN EXPERIMENTAL INVESTIGATION OF ECONOMIC AND PSYCHOLOGICAL HYPOTHESES* PREFERENCE REVERSAL: AN EXPERIMENTAL INVESTIGATION OF ECONOMIC AND PSYCHOLOGICAL HYPOTHESES* by Robin Cubitt** Alistair Munro** Chris Starmer*** * Research for this paper was funded by the Economic and

More information

ASSOCIATION FOR CONSUMER RESEARCH

ASSOCIATION FOR CONSUMER RESEARCH ASSOCIATION FOR CONSUMER RESEARCH Labovitz School of Business & Economics, University of Minnesota Duluth, 11 E. Superior Street, Suite 210, Duluth, MN 55802 Time Pressure and the Compromise and Attraction

More information

Response mode, compatibility, and dual-processes in the evaluation of simple gambles: An eye-tracking investigation

Response mode, compatibility, and dual-processes in the evaluation of simple gambles: An eye-tracking investigation Judgment and Decision Making, Vol. 7, No. 4, July 2012, pp. 427 440 Response mode, compatibility, and dual-processes in the evaluation of simple gambles: An eye-tracking investigation Enrico Rubaltelli

More information

The role of non-transparent matching methods in avoiding preference reversals in the evaluation of health outcomes. Fernando I.

The role of non-transparent matching methods in avoiding preference reversals in the evaluation of health outcomes. Fernando I. The role of non-transparent matching methods in avoiding preference reversals in the evaluation of health outcomes Fernando I. Sánchez Martínez Universidad de Murcia, Spain Jose Luis Pinto Prades* Glasgow

More information

Effect of Choice Set on Valuation of Risky Prospects

Effect of Choice Set on Valuation of Risky Prospects Effect of Choice Set on Valuation of Risky Prospects Neil Stewart (neil.stewart@warwick.ac.uk) Nick Chater (nick.chater@warwick.ac.uk) Henry P. Stott (hstott@owc.com) Department of Psychology, University

More information

Group Assignment #1: Concept Explication. For each concept, ask and answer the questions before your literature search.

Group Assignment #1: Concept Explication. For each concept, ask and answer the questions before your literature search. Group Assignment #1: Concept Explication 1. Preliminary identification of the concept. Identify and name each concept your group is interested in examining. Questions to asked and answered: Is each concept

More information

An Investigation of Factors Influencing Causal Attributions in Managerial Decision Making

An Investigation of Factors Influencing Causal Attributions in Managerial Decision Making Marketing Letters 9:3 (1998): 301 312 1998 Kluwer Academic Publishers, Manufactured in The Netherlands An Investigation of Factors Influencing Causal Attributions in Managerial Decision Making SUNDER NARAYANAN

More information

Prospect Relativity: How Choice Options Influence Decision Under Risk. Neil Stewart, Nick Chater, Henry P. Stott, and Stian Reimers

Prospect Relativity: How Choice Options Influence Decision Under Risk. Neil Stewart, Nick Chater, Henry P. Stott, and Stian Reimers Prospect Relativity 1 Running Head: PROSPECT RELATIVITY Prospect Relativity: How Choice Options Influence Decision Under Risk Neil Stewart, Nick Chater, Henry P. Stott, and Stian Reimers University of

More information

Limitations of Additive Conjoint Scaling Procedures: Detecting Nonadditivity When Additivity Is Known to Be Violated

Limitations of Additive Conjoint Scaling Procedures: Detecting Nonadditivity When Additivity Is Known to Be Violated _ -- ~---- ~-- ~-- - -- - ----- Limitations of Additive Conjoint Scaling Procedures: Detecting Nonadditivity When Additivity Is Known to Be Violated Thomas E. Nygren Ohio State University Two sets of three-outcome

More information

04/12/2014. Research Methods in Psychology. Chapter 6: Independent Groups Designs. What is your ideas? Testing

04/12/2014. Research Methods in Psychology. Chapter 6: Independent Groups Designs. What is your ideas? Testing Research Methods in Psychology Chapter 6: Independent Groups Designs 1 Why Psychologists Conduct Experiments? What is your ideas? 2 Why Psychologists Conduct Experiments? Testing Hypotheses derived from

More information

Explaining outcome type interactions with frame: Aspiration level and the value function

Explaining outcome type interactions with frame: Aspiration level and the value function Memory & Cognition 28, 36 (4), 838-848 doi: 1.3758/MC.36.4.838 Explaining outcome type interactions with frame: Aspiration level and the value function AMBER N. BLOOMFIELD DePaul University, Chicago, Illinois

More information

Discrimination and Generalization in Pattern Categorization: A Case for Elemental Associative Learning

Discrimination and Generalization in Pattern Categorization: A Case for Elemental Associative Learning Discrimination and Generalization in Pattern Categorization: A Case for Elemental Associative Learning E. J. Livesey (el253@cam.ac.uk) P. J. C. Broadhurst (pjcb3@cam.ac.uk) I. P. L. McLaren (iplm2@cam.ac.uk)

More information

An Experimental Test of Loss Aversion and Scale Compatibility. Han Bleichrodt, imta, Erasmus University, Rotterdam, The Netherlands

An Experimental Test of Loss Aversion and Scale Compatibility. Han Bleichrodt, imta, Erasmus University, Rotterdam, The Netherlands An Experimental Test of Loss Aversion and Scale Compatibility Han Bleichrodt, imta, Erasmus University, Rotterdam, The Netherlands Jose Luis Pinto, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona, Spain Address correspondence

More information

Evaluating framing e ects

Evaluating framing e ects Journal of Economic Psychology 22 2001) 91±101 www.elsevier.com/locate/joep Evaluating framing e ects James N. Druckman * Department of Political Science, University of Minnesota, 1414 Social Sciences

More information

Cognitive and Neural Processes of Constucted Preferences

Cognitive and Neural Processes of Constucted Preferences University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Publicly Accessible Penn Dissertations 1-1-2015 Cognitive and Neural Processes of Constucted Preferences Betty Viechnicki University of Pennsylvania, bettyekim@gmail.com

More information

How financial incentives and cognitive abilities. affect task performance in laboratory settings: an illustration

How financial incentives and cognitive abilities. affect task performance in laboratory settings: an illustration How financial incentives and cognitive abilities affect task performance in laboratory settings: an illustration Ondrej Rydval, Andreas Ortmann CERGE-EI, Prague, Czech Republic April 2004 Abstract Drawing

More information

Preference reversals in decision making under risk are accompanied by changes in attention to different attributes

Preference reversals in decision making under risk are accompanied by changes in attention to different attributes ORIGINAL RESEARCH ARTICLE published: 9 July 22 doi:.3389/fnins.22.9 Preference reversals in decision making under risk are accompanied by changes in attention to different attributes Betty E. Kim, Darryl

More information

How Does Prospect Theory Reflect Heuristics Probability Sensitivity in Risky Choice?

How Does Prospect Theory Reflect Heuristics Probability Sensitivity in Risky Choice? How Does Prospect Theory Reflect Heuristics Probability Sensitivity in Risky Choice? Renata S. Suter (suter@mpib-berlin.mpg.de) Max Planck Institute for Human Development, Lentzeallee 94, 495 Berlin, Germany

More information

FURTHER TESTS OE ASPIRATION LEVEL EFFECTS IN RISKY CHOICE BEHAVIORf

FURTHER TESTS OE ASPIRATION LEVEL EFFECTS IN RISKY CHOICE BEHAVIORf MANAGEMENT SCIENCE VoL 27. No. 8. August 1981 Printed in U.S.A. FURTHER TESTS OE ASPIRATION LEVEL EFFECTS IN RISKY CHOICE BEHAVIORf JOHN W. PAYNE, t DAN J. LAUGHHUNNJ AND ROY CRUM This Note extends the

More information

Introduction to Preference and Decision Making

Introduction to Preference and Decision Making Introduction to Preference and Decision Making Psychology 466: Judgment & Decision Making Instructor: John Miyamoto 10/31/2017: Lecture 06-1 Note: This Powerpoint presentation may contain macros that I

More information

One of the main objectives facing marketers is to present

One of the main objectives facing marketers is to present Controlling the Information Flow: Effects on Consumers Decision Making and Preferences DAN ARIELY* One of the main objectives facing marketers is to present consumers with information on which to base

More information

How People Estimate Effect Sizes: The Role of Means and Standard Deviations

How People Estimate Effect Sizes: The Role of Means and Standard Deviations How People Estimate Effect Sizes: The Role of Means and Standard Deviations Motoyuki Saito (m-saito@kwansei.ac.jp) Department of Psychological Science, Kwansei Gakuin University Hyogo 662-8501, JAPAN Abstract

More information

How Categories Shape Causality

How Categories Shape Causality How Categories Shape Causality Michael R. Waldmann (michael.waldmann@bio.uni-goettingen.de) Department of Psychology, University of Göttingen, Gosslerstr. 14, 37073 Göttingen, Germany York Hagmayer (york.hagmayer@bio.uni-goettingen.de)

More information

Are We Rational? Lecture 23

Are We Rational? Lecture 23 Are We Rational? Lecture 23 1 To Err is Human Alexander Pope, An Essay on Criticism (1711) Categorization Proper Sets vs. Prototypes and Exemplars Judgment and Decision-Making Algorithms vs. Heuristics

More information

Loss Aversion and Scale Compatibility in Two-Attribute Trade-Offs

Loss Aversion and Scale Compatibility in Two-Attribute Trade-Offs Journal of Mathematical Psychology 46, 315 337 (2002) doi:10.1006/jmps.2001.1390 Loss Aversion and Scale Compatibility in Two-Attribute Trade-Offs Han Bleichrodt Erasmus University and Jose Luis Pinto

More information

Sawtooth Software. The Number of Levels Effect in Conjoint: Where Does It Come From and Can It Be Eliminated? RESEARCH PAPER SERIES

Sawtooth Software. The Number of Levels Effect in Conjoint: Where Does It Come From and Can It Be Eliminated? RESEARCH PAPER SERIES Sawtooth Software RESEARCH PAPER SERIES The Number of Levels Effect in Conjoint: Where Does It Come From and Can It Be Eliminated? Dick Wittink, Yale University Joel Huber, Duke University Peter Zandan,

More information

CLEO RESEARCH PAPER SERIES LAW & ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPER SERIES

CLEO RESEARCH PAPER SERIES LAW & ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPER SERIES Construction of Preferences by Constraint Satisfaction (PSYCHOLOGICAL SCIENCE, 15(5), 331 (2004)) Dan Simon, Daniel C. Krawczyk, Keith J. Holyoak USC CLEO Research Paper No. C03-19 USC Law and Economics

More information

Lessons in biostatistics

Lessons in biostatistics Lessons in biostatistics The test of independence Mary L. McHugh Department of Nursing, School of Health and Human Services, National University, Aero Court, San Diego, California, USA Corresponding author:

More information

A Comparison of Three Measures of the Association Between a Feature and a Concept

A Comparison of Three Measures of the Association Between a Feature and a Concept A Comparison of Three Measures of the Association Between a Feature and a Concept Matthew D. Zeigenfuse (mzeigenf@msu.edu) Department of Psychology, Michigan State University East Lansing, MI 48823 USA

More information

entertefor Deon tus-o tu

entertefor Deon tus-o tu lv;. SCHiQOL OF BUSINESS~.'7'j Th mato cuayadefr d ns entertefor Deon tus-o tu Th e Fuefja-Sc hool o Busi ness I'tike Linivermity Durham, inort, 7 Carolna 2770&. ONR - Technical Report 89-3 The Impact

More information

Constructing Preference From Experience: The Endowment Effect Reflected in External Information Search

Constructing Preference From Experience: The Endowment Effect Reflected in External Information Search Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition 2012, Vol. 38, No. 4, 1108 1116 2012 American Psychological Association 0278-7393/12/$12.00 DOI: 10.1037/a0027637 RESEARCH REPORT Constructing

More information

Does momentary accessibility influence metacomprehension judgments? The influence of study judgment lags on accessibility effects

Does momentary accessibility influence metacomprehension judgments? The influence of study judgment lags on accessibility effects Psychonomic Bulletin & Review 26, 13 (1), 6-65 Does momentary accessibility influence metacomprehension judgments? The influence of study judgment lags on accessibility effects JULIE M. C. BAKER and JOHN

More information

Dimensions of Health and Illness: Toward an Integrated Model

Dimensions of Health and Illness: Toward an Integrated Model I Dimensions of Health and Illness: Toward an Integrated Model Introduction The six chapters in this section emphasize the need to incorporate new dimensions into the prevailing definitions of illness

More information

Exploring a Counterintuitive Finding with Methodological Implications

Exploring a Counterintuitive Finding with Methodological Implications Exploring a Counterintuitive Finding with Methodological Implications Why is 9 > 221 in a Between-subjects Design? Stuart J. McKelvie Department of Psychology Bishop s University 2600 College Street, Sherbrooke,

More information

PLS 506 Mark T. Imperial, Ph.D. Lecture Notes: Reliability & Validity

PLS 506 Mark T. Imperial, Ph.D. Lecture Notes: Reliability & Validity PLS 506 Mark T. Imperial, Ph.D. Lecture Notes: Reliability & Validity Measurement & Variables - Initial step is to conceptualize and clarify the concepts embedded in a hypothesis or research question with

More information

2 Critical thinking guidelines

2 Critical thinking guidelines What makes psychological research scientific? Precision How psychologists do research? Skepticism Reliance on empirical evidence Willingness to make risky predictions Openness Precision Begin with a Theory

More information

The role of training in experimental auctions

The role of training in experimental auctions AUA Working Paper Series No. 2010-2 February 2010 The role of training in experimental auctions Andreas Drichoutis Department of Economics University of Ioannina, Greece adrihout@cc.uoi.gr Rodolfo M. Nayga,

More information

PERCEPTUAL CONDITIONS AFFECTING EASE OF ASSOCIATION

PERCEPTUAL CONDITIONS AFFECTING EASE OF ASSOCIATION Journal of Experimental Psychology 1972, Vol. 93, No. 1, 176-180 PERCEPTUAL CONDITIONS AFFECTING EASE OF ASSOCIATION PETER G. ARNOLD AND GORDON H. BOWER 2 Stanford University Four experiments replicated

More information

Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition

Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition Conflict and Bias in Heuristic Judgment Sudeep Bhatia Online First Publication, September 29, 2016. http://dx.doi.org/10.1037/xlm0000307

More information

Different Scales for Different Frames: The Role of Subjective Scales and Experience in Explaining Attribute Framing Effects

Different Scales for Different Frames: The Role of Subjective Scales and Experience in Explaining Attribute Framing Effects 1 Different Scales for Different Frames: The Role of Subjective Scales and Experience in Explaining Attribute Framing Effects CHRIS JANISZEWSKI* TIM SILK ALAN D. J. COOKE September, 2002 Forthcoming Journal

More information

Chapter 2 Ordinal Utility and Preference Reversal Phenomenon

Chapter 2 Ordinal Utility and Preference Reversal Phenomenon Chapter 2 Ordinal Utility and Preference Reversal Phenomenon Chapter 1 described that decision-making phenomena are broadly divisible into those under certainty, those under risk, and others under uncertainty.

More information

PSYCHOLOGY : JUDGMENT AND DECISION MAKING

PSYCHOLOGY : JUDGMENT AND DECISION MAKING PSYCHOLOGY 4136-100: JUDGMENT AND DECISION MAKING http://psych.colorado.edu/~vanboven/teaching/psyc4136/psyc4136.html Monday, 1:00-3:30, Muenzinger D156B Instructor Assistant Dr. Leaf Van Boven Jordan

More information

What s in Your Wallet? Psychophysical Biases in the Estimation of Money. Priya Raghubir Mario Capizzani Joydeep Srivastava* November 1, 2016

What s in Your Wallet? Psychophysical Biases in the Estimation of Money. Priya Raghubir Mario Capizzani Joydeep Srivastava* November 1, 2016 What s in Your Wallet? Psychophysical Biases in the Estimation of Money Priya Raghubir Mario Capizzani Joydeep Srivastava* November 1, 2016 *Priya Raghubir is the Dean Abraham L. Gitlow Professor of Business,

More information

T. Kushnir & A. Gopnik (2005 ). Young children infer causal strength from probabilities and interventions. Psychological Science 16 (9):

T. Kushnir & A. Gopnik (2005 ). Young children infer causal strength from probabilities and interventions. Psychological Science 16 (9): Probabilities and Interventions 1 Running Head: PROBABILITIES AND INTERVENTIONS T. Kushnir & A. Gopnik (2005 ). Young children infer causal strength from probabilities and interventions. Psychological

More information

The effects of payout and probability magnitude on the Allais paradox

The effects of payout and probability magnitude on the Allais paradox Memory & Cognition 2008, 36 (5), 1013-1023 doi: 10.3758/MC.36.5.1013 The effects of payout and probability magnitude on the Allais paradox BETHANY Y J. WEBER Rutgers University, New Brunswick, New Jersey

More information

Problems of Policy Implementation in Distributed Decision Systems. Paul Slovic. Decision Research/A Branch of Perceptronics, Inc.

Problems of Policy Implementation in Distributed Decision Systems. Paul Slovic. Decision Research/A Branch of Perceptronics, Inc. Problems of Policy Implementation in Distributed Decision Systems Paul Slovic Decision Research/A Branch of Perceptronics, Inc. 1201 Oak Street Eugene, Oregon 97401 In R. Weissinger-Baylon & J. March (Eds.),

More information

Interpreting Instructional Cues in Task Switching Procedures: The Role of Mediator Retrieval

Interpreting Instructional Cues in Task Switching Procedures: The Role of Mediator Retrieval Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition 2006, Vol. 32, No. 3, 347 363 Copyright 2006 by the American Psychological Association 0278-7393/06/$12.00 DOI: 10.1037/0278-7393.32.3.347

More information

Vagueness, Context Dependence and Interest Relativity

Vagueness, Context Dependence and Interest Relativity Chris Kennedy Seminar on Vagueness University of Chicago 2 May, 2006 Vagueness, Context Dependence and Interest Relativity 1 Questions about vagueness Graff (2000) summarizes the challenge for a theory

More information

Methods of eliciting time preferences for health A pilot study

Methods of eliciting time preferences for health A pilot study Methods of eliciting time preferences for health A pilot study Dorte Gyrd-Hansen Health Economics Papers 2000:1 Methods of eliciting time preferences for health A pilot study Dorte Gyrd-Hansen Contents

More information

Verbal representation in task order control: An examination with transition and task cues in random task switching

Verbal representation in task order control: An examination with transition and task cues in random task switching Memory & Cognition 2009, 37 (7), 1040-1050 doi:10.3758/mc.37.7.1040 Verbal representation in task order control: An examination with transition and task cues in random task switching ERINA SAEKI AND SATORU

More information

Analysis of Human-Human and Human-Computer Agent Interactions from the Viewpoint of Design of and Attribution to a Partner

Analysis of Human-Human and Human-Computer Agent Interactions from the Viewpoint of Design of and Attribution to a Partner Analysis of - and -Computer Interactions from the Viewpoint of Design of and to a Partner Kazuhisa Miwa (miwa@is.nagoya-u.ac.jp) Hitoshi Terai (terai@cog.human.nagoya-u.ac.jp) Graduate School of Information

More information

Anticipated Emotions as Guides to Choice

Anticipated Emotions as Guides to Choice 210 VOLUME 10, NUMBER 6, DECEMBER 2001 Anticipated Emotions as Guides to Choice Barbara A. Mellers 1 and A. Peter McGraw Department of Psychology, The Ohio State University, Columbus, Ohio Abstract When

More information

A Possible Explanation to Yea-saying in Contingent Valuation Surveys*

A Possible Explanation to Yea-saying in Contingent Valuation Surveys* A Possible Explanation to Yea-saying in Contingent Valuation Surveys* Todd L. Cherry a Appalachian State University Peter Frykblom b Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences 21 October 2000 Abstract

More information

Reveal Relationships in Categorical Data

Reveal Relationships in Categorical Data SPSS Categories 15.0 Specifications Reveal Relationships in Categorical Data Unleash the full potential of your data through perceptual mapping, optimal scaling, preference scaling, and dimension reduction

More information

Teaching A Way of Implementing Statistical Methods for Ordinal Data to Researchers

Teaching A Way of Implementing Statistical Methods for Ordinal Data to Researchers Journal of Mathematics and System Science (01) 8-1 D DAVID PUBLISHING Teaching A Way of Implementing Statistical Methods for Ordinal Data to Researchers Elisabeth Svensson Department of Statistics, Örebro

More information

What a speaker s choice of frame reveals: Reference points, frame selection, and framing effects

What a speaker s choice of frame reveals: Reference points, frame selection, and framing effects Psychonomic Bulletin & Review 2003, 10 (3), 596-602 What a speaker s choice of frame reveals: Reference points, frame selection, and framing effects CRAIG R. M. MCKENZIE and JONATHAN D. NELSON University

More information

The Role of Expectations in Comparisons

The Role of Expectations in Comparisons Psychological Review 2000, Vol. 107, No. 2, 345-357 Copyright 2000 by (he American Psychological Association, Inc. 0033-295X/00/S5-00 DOT: 10.1037//OG33-295X.107.2.345 The Role of Expectations in Comparisons

More information

S"TX. Revised - A Study of Comparative Judgments. of Numerical and Verbal Attribute Labels. Faculty Working Paper

STX. Revised - A Study of Comparative Judgments. of Numerical and Verbal Attribute Labels. Faculty Working Paper Faculty Working Paper 92-0125 35 1992:125 COPY 2 S"TX Revised - A Study of Comparative Judgments of Numerical and Verbal Attribute Labels The Library of the JUL * W* UnWorsIT* of tlunnls ijrrona-nrcrr^

More information

STOCHASTIC CHOICE HEURISTICS *

STOCHASTIC CHOICE HEURISTICS * Acta Psychologica 56 (1984) 153-166 North-Holland STOCHASTIC CHOICE HEURISTICS * K. Michael ASCHENBRENNER, Dietrich ALBERT and Franz SCHMALHOFER University of Heidelberg, West-Germany A class of stochastic

More information

CAHIER DE RECHERCHE n E3

CAHIER DE RECHERCHE n E3 CAHIER DE RECHERCHE n 2010-02 E3 THE MESSAGE FRAMING OF HEALTH COMMUNICATIONS : HOW TO ELICIT HIGHER INTENTION TO GET AN ANNUAL PAP TEST? BALBO LAURIE Unité Mixte de Recherche CNRS / Université Pierre

More information

Investigations of consumer decision making suggest that

Investigations of consumer decision making suggest that The Effect of Regulatory Orientation and Decision Strategy on Brand Judgments ECHO WEN WAN JIEWEN HONG BRIAN STERNTHAL* Four studies investigate how consumers regulatory orientation and the decision strategies

More information

PSYCHOLOGICAL SCIENCE. Research Report. CONFLICT AND THE STOCHASTIC-DOMINANCE PRINCIPLE OF DECISION MAKING Adele Diederich 1 and Jerome R.

PSYCHOLOGICAL SCIENCE. Research Report. CONFLICT AND THE STOCHASTIC-DOMINANCE PRINCIPLE OF DECISION MAKING Adele Diederich 1 and Jerome R. Research Report CONFLICT AND THE STOCHASTIC-DOMINANCE PRINCIPLE OF DECISION MAKING Adele Diederich 1 and Jerome R. Busemeyer 2 1 Univesitat Oldenburg, Oldenburg, Germany, and 2 Indiana University Abstract

More information

Broadening the Conditions for Illusory Correlation Formation: Implications for Judging Minority Groups

Broadening the Conditions for Illusory Correlation Formation: Implications for Judging Minority Groups BASIC AND APPLIED SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY, 21(4), 263 279 Copyright 1999, Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Inc. Broadening the Conditions for Illusory Correlation Formation: Implications for Judging Minority Groups

More information

Contrast and the justification of effort

Contrast and the justification of effort Psychonomic Bulletin & Review 2005, 12 (2), 335-339 Contrast and the justification of effort EMILY D. KLEIN, RAMESH S. BHATT, and THOMAS R. ZENTALL University of Kentucky, Lexington, Kentucky When humans

More information

Choices and affective reactions to negative life events: An averaging/summation analysis

Choices and affective reactions to negative life events: An averaging/summation analysis Judgment and Decision Making, Vol. 3, No. 5, June 2008, pp. 425 434 Choices and affective reactions to negative life events: An averaging/summation analysis John J. Seta University of North Carolina at

More information

The Perception of Own Death Risk from Wildlife-Vehicle Collisions: the case of Newfoundland s Moose

The Perception of Own Death Risk from Wildlife-Vehicle Collisions: the case of Newfoundland s Moose The Perception of Own Death Risk from Wildlife-Vehicle Collisions: the case of Newfoundland s Moose Roberto Martínez-Espiñeira Department of Economics, Memorial University of Newfoundland, Canada and Henrik

More information