Valuing health using visual analogue scales and rank data: does the visual analogue scale contain cardinal information?

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Valuing health using visual analogue scales and rank data: does the visual analogue scale contain cardinal information?"

Transcription

1 Academic Unit of Health Economics LEEDS INSTITUTE OF HEALTH SCIENCES Working Paper Series No. 09_01 Valuing health using visual analogue scales and rank data: does the visual analogue scale contain cardinal information? Hulme, C. a, * and Edlin, R. a a Academic Unit of Health Economics, University of Leeds, Leeds, UK * Dr Claire Hulme Academic Unit of Health Economics Leeds Institute of Health Sciences University of Leeds 101 Clarendon Road LEEDS LS2 9LJ Tel: +44 (0) c.t.hulme@leeds.ac.uk Disclaimer The series enables staff and student researchers based at or affiliated with the AUHE to make recent work and work in progress available to a wider audience. The work and ideas reported here do not represent the final position and need to be treated as work in progress. The material and views expressed in the series are solely those of the authors and should not be quoted without their permission.

2 2 Abstract Valuation studies have favoured standard gamble (SG) and time trade off techniques (TTO) over visual analogue scales (VAS). The lack of observable trade off properties of VAS precludes preferences being measured on a cardinal scale. The inferences, and indeed the premise, of many perceived VAS deficiencies have been debated and, as part of this on-going debate, Brazier and McCabe (2007) asked whether VAS data added anything to rank data; echoing the suggestion that VAS functioned primarily as a prop for ranking exercises (Torrance et al 2001). Previous studies suggest that analyses of ordinal (rank data) can provide valuation functions broadly equivalent to cardinal health state data models (Salomon, 2003; McCabe et al, 2006). This paper adds to the debate by considering whether ordinal preferences, cardinal differences, and cardinal scores from VAS data provide substantively different valuation algorithms. That is, is potentially valuable information lost by using ordinal (rank) data rather than cardinal VAS scores? In the case where a cardinal difference model can provide a substantively better fit than an ordinal preference model, then we can say that the VAS contains useful cardinal information that cannot be incorporated into an ordinal model. A further aim is to assess whether VAS-based ordinal preferences (rather than TTO- or SG-based ordinal preferences) are likely to be sufficient reliably to inform policy. Using rescaled data from a UK general population survey seven separate random effects logit regressions were carried out for ordinal preferences and seven for cardinal differences. In contrast to previous studies the analyses found that ordinal preference models appear to give different results to cardinal data. Ordinal preference data performed worse than the cardinal difference suggesting that: (1) VAS contains at least some relevant and useful cardinal data and (2) ignoring such data worsens performance of the resulting measures. Keywords: Visual analogue scales; rating scale; ordinal preferences; health state valuation; preference-based health measures

3 3 Introduction The role of visual analogue scales (VAS) in valuation studies has been extensively discussed. Valuation studies have favoured standard gamble (SG) and time trade off techniques (TTO) over VAS with proponents of the former techniques arguing that the lack of theoretical foundation means that valuations using VAS cannot relate to the underlying theory of QALYs (Johannesson et al, 1996). The lack of observable trade off properties precludes preferences being measured on a cardinal scale. VAS data have also been criticised for the absence of uncertainty and problems with bias due to framing effects including context bias and end state aversion (Parkin and Devlin, 2006; Torrance et al, 2001). Torrance et al also highlight issues associated with the lack of agreement between VAS and SG results and anchoring, in particular definitions such as best imaginable and worst imaginable state. The inferences, and indeed the premise, of many perceived VAS deficiencies have been debated (Torrance et al, 2001; Parkin and Devlin, 2006; Brazier and McCabe, 2007) and, as part of this ongoing debate, recently Brazier and McCabe (2007) asked whether VAS data added anything to rank data; echoing Torrance and colleagues suggestion that VAS functioned primarily as a prop for ranking exercises. Previous studies suggest that analyses of ordinal (rank data) can provide valuation functions broadly equivalent to cardinal health state data models (Salomon, 2003; McCabe et al, 2006). Using a conditional logit model, Salomon proposes estimation of cardinal values be carried out using aggregate data on ordinal rankings. The model uses TTO data from a UK general population survey, The Measurement and Valuation of Health (MVH) (Dolan et al, 1994). Within the survey health states were described using the EQ-5D descriptive system (five dimensions: mobility, self care, usual activities, pain/discomfort, anxiety/depression) and respondents asked to describe their own health state before ranking 13 hypothetical states (taken from 42) plus dead and unconscious. Rankings were followed by ratings of the same states using a VAS. Finally a series of TTO questions were used for the 13 states. Respondents initially indicated whether each state was preferred to dead. When considering a state j, the model assumes that respondent i will have a latent utility Uij composed of a systematic component value ( j ) and an error term ( ij ). When comparing two states, it is assumed that the state with the higher latent utility estimate will be preferred. If each health state has the same underlying value across all respondents, then State j will be preferred over

4 4 State k where the difference in error terms ( ) is less than the difference in underlying values ( j k ), and State k where not. ij ik The individual-level rank data are treated as a series of choices. Initially one state, with the best rank, is chosen over all others, then the state with the second rank over all others with the exception of the first and so on. This is equivalent to a ranking of n states and provides n(n-1)/2 discrete preferences. The model assumes that the expected value of the latent utility of each health state is a linear function of the ratings of the EQ-5D domains j rescaled in three distinct ways: θ. Before running the regression the data are x j 1. normalisation to match the scale of observed TTO values in the data 2. normalisation to produce a utility of 0 for the state 3. normalisation to produce a utility of 0 for dead Additional analyses run the rankings in reverse order to take account of a right skewed distribution in order to consider whether this produces important differences. Salomon found all three rescaling options predictions were strongly correlated with the observed TTO values (Pearson s r for Options 1 and 2 and for Option 3). Using ICC, normalisation to match the scale of observed TTO values in the data was the best fit and similar to that of the TTO (0.974 vs ). Comparison of modelled and observed TTO values by state show that the four states with the largest discrepancies between predicted values from the rank model and mean observed TTO values, all included Level 3 on the dimension of pain, and all were states with the largest differences in rank positions between the direct ordering exercise and the TTO. Comparison of inverted and non-inverted rank orderings showed comparable results and when compared to the observed TTO values were almost identical to the main model. These results led Salomon to the conclusion that the information content of aggregate rank data is similar to that of the TTO. However, Salomon highlights a number of important limitations or areas of further research including whether utilities are correlated across health states at the level of the individual (the assumption of independence from irrelevant alternatives) and choice of scale anchors which is complicated by differences in the relative ranking of dead between the two methods (unlike the SG and TTO being dead is not a health state for VAS which causes confusion for respondents (Brazier and McCabe, 2007).

5 5 Building on Salomon s model, McCabe et al (2006) estimate conditional logistic regression models for HUI2 and SF-6D using ordinal preference data to explore whether the results are comparable to those estimated by SG. Both the HUI2 and SF-6D have six dimensions (HUI2 sensation, mobility, emotion, cognition, self-care and pain; SF-6D physical functioning, role limitations, social functioning, pain, mental health and vitality). HUI2 respondents ranked eight health states from its classification plus full health and dead (McCabe et al 2005a; McCabe et al 2005b) and then valued the same states using SG. For the SF-6D a representative sample of the UK population were asked to value a sample of SF-6D health states using SG. Respondents were asked to rank five health states plus the best and worse states defined by the SF-6D. Using SG techniques respondents valued each one of five health states with against the best and worst SF-6D health states as alternative outcomes and then valued the worse measurable SF-6D (the pits state) in relation to dead. A sixth SG valuation was dependent on whether respondents had value PITS higher or lower than dead. McCabe et al s model, like Salomon s, assumes independence of irrelevant alternative (ranking of the pair not affected by other states ranked in the same exercise). The model assumes that respondent i will have a latent utility Uij when considering a state j, now comprising a systematic component value ( j ) and an error term ( ij ) and a dummy variable for dead (D). Again, respondents are assumed to choose the option with greater latent utility, and the expected value of the unobserved utility is a linear function of categorical level on the dimensions of each dataset: j x j θ D, where x j is composed of dummy variables for all dimension-level combinations (top score items appear as the baseline). All coefficients are rescaled by 1 to provide predictions at dead (0) and full health (1). In the case of the HUI2 the results show similarity between rank and SG models; although the former has one more inconsistency and doesn t distinguish as clearly between levels of mobility. For the SF- 6D model the rank model differs to that of the SG. Despite the rank model having a lower number of inconsistencies the predictive performance is better in the SG model. McCabe et al also note that there is evidence in the models that the assumption of independence doesn t hold that models are sensitive to exclusion of states ranked highly or lowly. They conclude that the rank models performed better than expected given the different informational content and that the results are consistent with the existence of a latent utility function.

6 6 The two studies outlined show promise for the use of rank data in valuing health. Whilst previous papers use TTO and SG, it is arguably inefficient to use intensive survey methods in order to obtain rank data only. If rank data are sufficient to create a valuation algorithm, then VAS values may be an appropriate way to obtain this data. Parkin and Devlin (2006) argue that VAS may provide some advantages over more complex methods in areas of feasibility, reliability and practicality (in particular, by allowing postal surveys). This paper uses the same dataset as Salomon but concentrates on VAS data. We consider whether the information contained in the VAS rank data provides similar results to the cardinal VAS data. That is, do we lose potentially valuable information by using ordinal (rank) data rather than cardinal VAS scores? The ordinal data infers a preference between two states, which provides different information than the VAS score the ordinal data considers the difference between states but does not consider the intensity of preference between them, whilst the cardinal score does not (in itself) consider differences between states but provides a level of utility. More useful comparisons may be between ordinal preferences (between states) and cardinal differences (between states), and cardinal differences (between states) and the VAS scores (level only). These cardinal differences have been considered previously. Dolan and Roberts (2002) investigated the cardinal preferences between states and explored whether a tariff with better predictive ability can be calculated using differences between EQ5D states and rather than the levels themselves. Roberts and Dolan (2004) also consider the degree to which individual ordinal preferences (inferred from TTO responses) correspond to differences in the mean TTO levels across individuals. They suggest a large degree of heterogeneity in preferences between individuals; this necessitates the use of random effects within this paper. This paper considers whether ordinal preferences, cardinal differences, and cardinal scores from VAS data provide substantively different valuation algorithms. In the case where a cardinal difference model can provide a substantively better fit than an ordinal preference model, then we can say that the VAS contains useful cardinal information that cannot be incorporated into an ordinal model. A further aim is to assess whether VAS -based ordinal preferences (rather than TTO- or SG-based ordinal preferences) are likely to be sufficient reliably to inform policy.

7 7 Data and preparation of dependent values Whilst the data from the UK general population survey (Dolan et al, 1994) is outlined in brief above, in more detail 3395 interviews were conducted; the sample was representative of the general population. Each interview consisted of five components. The first was self reported health using the EQ-5D descriptive system and VAS; secondly a ranking exercise consisting of 15 pre-determined states in which each state (including full health and dead) lasts for 10 years, with the dead state after 10 years. This was followed by VAS rating of the same states on a 0 to 100 scale. The next component was a TTO exercise in which full health and dead were removed (leaving just 13 states). VAS scores are used here without applying a correction for range frequency bias (Parducci and Weddell, 1986). Schwartz (1998) found that some VAS data appeared to provide cardinal values only when corrected for this bias. We considered applying the Parducci-Weddell correction (assuming an equal contribution to underlying value and spreading factors, w = 0.5) but found that this would have required omitting nearly half our data. Here, 30.5% of individual observations were above the maximum figure feasible under rank-frequency bias and a further 12.3% of observations are below the minimum feasible figure. For each respondent, individual VAS scores were first rescaled with dead and full health at 0 and 1. Those states rated worse than dead were rescaled so that the worse conceivable health state (i.e. 0 on the original VAS scale) would receive the value -1. (In the analysis of the TTO data, a similar assumption was made to limit the lowest value received to -1.) Three variables were defined as dependent variables for the subsequent analysis. When considering comparisons of states, the ORD and CARD variables are used. Here, the ORD variable takes the value 1 if the first state in a comparison is preferred, 0 if the second state is preferred, and 0.5 given indifference between them. Details of the assumptions used to form comparisons appear in the following section. The CARD variable presents the difference in (scaled) cardinal values between the states. The LEVEL variable considers the disutility from full health, and is used within the regressions to predict cardinal levels. When reporting coefficients, all results from the cardinal level regressions are multiplied by -1 in order to provide a measure of utility and hence greater comparability to the other results.

8 8 Analysis The existing literature uses a variety of methods, and some methods may be more or less appropriate to particular types of data than others. As such, the general aim is to identify an appropriate valuation algorithm for each type of data (ordinal preference, cardinal difference, VAS score) and compare their respective predictive abilities against mean EQ-5D VAS scores. Seven separate random effects logit regressions were carried out for different datasets representing ordinal preferences over dead, full health and the 13 states valued by each individual. Seven similar regressions were run for the cardinal differences between states using a standard random effects model. In both cases the random effect identifies individual respondents. All datasets were first prepared by scaling individual VAS responses against the values provided for dead (to 0) and full health (to 1). Values worse than dead were restricted to fall on the interval (0, -1] using the lower anchor of the VAS scale. The following groups were excluded: Those who failed to give a value for dead, full health, or the pits state (33333) Valued fewer than three other states in addition to these three Rated dead as better than full health, own health as worse than pits, or pits as better than full health. Rated fewer than three states better than dead. Of the 3395 individuals surveyed, 162 were excluded from the full MVH dataset, in comparison to the 84 exclusions in the original study. The seven datasets used in the regressions were constructed as follows. Pairwise combinations of all states: Exhaustive Following Salomon s methodology, our exhaustive dataset assumes independence of irrelevant alternatives between any two states. Here, the most preferred state in the ordinal ranking of n states is compared against the (n-1) states it is preferred to, the next state in our ordered list is compared against the (n-2) states (i.e. excluding the most preferred state), the next against (n-3) states and so on. Here the ranking of n states provides n(n-1)/2 preferences; for an individual providing 15 valuations, this leads to 105 distinct ordinal preferences and cardinal differences.

9 9 Extractions from a rank order: Proximate, Random 1, Random 2 Three datasets were prepared from a ranking between states. The proximate dataset uses the method from McCabe et al, and utilises each individual s orderings of the states. Here, the most preferred state was compared to the next most favoured state; this latter state to the one following, and so on. Each state typically appears on two occasions for an individual once against the next most preferred state, and once against the next least preferred state; the most and least preferred states only appear once. The rank order of n states provides n-1 preferences; for an individual providing 15 valuations, this leads to 14 distinct ordinal preferences and cardinal differences. In the Random 1 and Random 2 datasets a similar process was used but the states were not ordered by preference. Instead, a random order was generated between the states and the methodology above repeated to again provide n-1 distinct ordinal preferences and cardinal difference where n states were valued. Comparisons against a defined state: vs Full, vs Dead, vs Pits When constructing a regression based on cardinal differences Dolan and Roberts (2002) computed preferences against the EQ-5D state In theory, any state could be used for this purpose, and we consider full health, dead and pits here. In each case, preferences for n states will provide (n-1) ordinal preferences and cardinal differences. For each of these datasets, dummies were created that reflect the differences between two states in a comparison. Dead is coded as for full health with the exception of the values on the variable D (where dead is present as a first or second state, see Table 1 below). For example, suppose that the first state considered is full health, EQ-5D state and the second state considered is in which there are no problems in any domain with the exception of usual activities where the respondent indicates I am unable to perform my usual activities. Since the states are identical in all dimensions except usual activities, MO21, SC21, PD21, AD21, MO32, SC32, PD32, and AD32 all take the value 0. UA21 and UA32 both take the value 1, reflecting the higher health in the first state. D = 0 because neither state involves dead and N3 = -1 because only the second state involves a dimension at Level 3.

10 10 Table 1: Variable definitions Name Levels Coding MO21 Difference in mobility: levels 2 and 1 1 first state is level 1, SC21 Difference in self care: levels 2 and 1 UA21 Difference in usual activities: levels 2 and 1 PD21 Difference in pain/discomfort: levels 2 and 1 AD21 Difference in anxiety/depression: levels 2 and 1 second state level 2 or 3-1 first state is level 2 or 3, second state is level 1 0 all other cases MO32 Difference in mobility: levels 3 and 2 1 first state is level 1 or 2, SC32 Difference in self care: levels 3 and 2 UA32 Difference in usual activities: levels 3 and 2 PD32 Difference in pain/discomfort: levels 3 and 2 AD32 Difference in anxiety/depression: levels 3 and 2 second state level 3-1 first state is level 3, second state is level 1 or 2 0 all other cases D N3 Dead present as first or second state Is an EQ-5D 3 rd level present 1 state 1 is dead -1 state 2 is dead 0 dead not present in either state 1 first state has an EQ-5D level 3, second state has no EQ-5D level 3-1 first state has no EQ-5D level 3, second state has an EQ-5D level 3 0 all other cases Prior to all regressions except that involving LEVEL, data was randomly switched to eliminate a constant term in the cardinal differences regression. A uniform distribution on (0, 1) was estimated and a variable defined as to whether the value was above or below 0.5. If below 0.5, all the variables in the above table and CARD were multiplied by -1; in essence, the first and second states in any comparison were reversed. In these cases, ORD was recoded as 1 ORD. Where items were found to have the wrong sign, they were removed from the regression (in order of least significance to most significant). Results Table 2 displays the coefficients from the fifteen regressions. Bolded figures within the table indicate significance at 5%, with removed items left blank. The regressions differ in the number of insignificant and omitted items. In the regression on cardinal variable LEVEL all the EQ-5D variables in Table 1 above are significant with the exception of the N3 term; a similar pattern is observed in the cardinal Random 1, Random 2, and vs Dead models. All variables are significant in the exhaustive logit model

11 11 considering ordinal preferences including the N3 term. At the opposite extreme, the model considering ordinal preferences against the Dead state has only five EQ-5D significant variables with the correct sign (plus the constant): MO32, SC32, UA21, PD32, and AD32. In general, worsening health from Level 1 to Level 2 is unlikely to be sufficient for a health state to shift from better-thandead to worse-than-dead; the regression contains only one of five possible 2 1 shifts. Here, the cardinal model definitely outperforms the ordinal model. A fairer reflection of performance, however, is to consider the accuracy of a range of methodologies. Table 2: Regression coefficients from random effects and random effects logit models Exhaustive Logit Ranking: Preferences: Proximate Random 1 Random 2 vs FH vs Dead vs Pits CARDINAL LEVEL CARD CARD CARD CARD CARD CARD CARD MO MO SC SC UA UA PD PD AD AD D N Constant ORDINAL ORD ORD ORD ORD ORD ORD ORD MO MO SC SC UA UA PD PD AD AD D N Constant Bolded figures are significant at 5%. In order to compare the regression results against mean EQ-5D VAS scores, we estimate predictions for the 42 states valued in the MVH study and rescale these to the standard scale. (Unconscious was removed as there is no classification for this state on the EQ-5D.) Table 3 presents a summary of the cardinal difference and ordinal preference model fits, including their range and errors against the mean VAS scores. The range of the unscaled VAS predictions varies greatly, from for the cardinal Proximate model to -22 to 27 in the ordinal vs Full Health model. Scaled, the ordinal models appear typically place dead as the worst or near the worst

12 12 possible state (typically valued at around 0.00), whilst in the cardinal models the worst state is typically valued between -0.3 and Of the cardinal differences models, it appears that the vs Full Health model provides the lowest root mean squared error (RMSE) at 0.14 and also fewest absolute errors above 0.05, 0.10 and 0.20 (at 57%, 32% and 7% of cases). This model is taken to be our preferred cardinal difference model. For the ordinal difference models, it is clear that they have a generally higher RMSE (around 0.2 to 0.3 rather than ) and that three models appear to have a better performance than the others. Here, the Exhaustive, Random 1 and Random 2 models all have an RMSE around In all three cases, almost all cases have an absolute error above 0.05 and approximately half of the cases have an absolute error above We use the Exhaustive model as our preferred ordinal preference model but do so with caveats, as detailed in the discussion below. The performance of both the cardinal difference and ordinal preference models can be compared to that of the cardinal regression predicting LEVEL. Here, in contrast to other models, a lower proportion of predictions had absolute errors below 0.05 (50%), 0.10 (23%) and 0.20 (2%). Figure 1 presents the cumulative proportion of states by absolute error, where the higher values indicate superior fit. It is clear here that the VAS levels regression generally dominates, with the preferred cardinal difference model outperforming the preferred ordinal preference model. Table 3: Fit of the cardinal difference and ordinal preference models Exhaustive Ranking: Preferences vs: Logit Proximate Random 1 Random 2 Full health Death Pits CARDINAL (SCALED) DIFFERENCES MAX MIN ERRORS MAX RMSE by state %errors above % 84% 73% 73% 57% 75% 73% %errors above % 73% 45% 52% 32% 50% 48% %errors above % 59% 18% 18% 7% 18% 18% ORDINAL (SCALED) PREFERENCES MAX MIN ERRORS MAX RMSE by state

13 13 %errors above % 95% 93% 95% 95% 95% 95% %errors above % 91% 86% 84% 93% 95% 95% %errors above % 66% 48% 48% 64% 68% 84% Figure 1: Fit of the preferred models 100% 90% 80% 70% Cumulative Fit 60% 50% 40% VAS Levels Regression Cardinal (vs Full Health) Ordinal (Exploded Logit) 30% 20% 10% 0% Absolute Error Discussion Several features are of note within the models presented above, particularly in relation to which appear to perform poorly for certain types of data. For the cardinal data, the Proximate method appears to perform relatively poorly. This may be a feature of the data used here. In the MVH study, states were selected so that all individuals will consider two very mild states, three mild states, three intermediate states and three severe states. Here, the rankings between similarly severe states will typically involve very low cardinal differences between the states but potentially large differences in the descriptions of the states. As a result, the coefficients in this model are particularly small. This has the effect of reducing the range of unscaled health estimates, and exaggerating the possible range of health state values when anchored at 0 and 1. We might expect, and do observe, smaller unscaled coefficients and a similar lack of fit for the ordinal Proximate model. (In contrast the SGbased model used in McCabe et al considered states that were more evenly spread, so that the suppression of coefficient values observed here was not a factor.) For the ordinal data, the vs Full Health model has a very high coefficient on dead that is nonsignificant. By the exclusion criteria, being in full health is always preferred to being dead within our sample, so there is unanimity and the logit regression is unable to estimate a standard error for the

14 14 coefficient hence, the lack of significance. The implication of the large (unscaled) coefficient on dead is that the other coefficients also increase in value. The ordinal vs Dead and ordinal vs Pits models also perform relatively poorly in terms of the number of insignificant or omitted variables. Here, we can safely predict that most states will be preferred to being dead, that most states predicted by the EQ-5D will be preferred to the worst state describable by the instrument. It is probably unsurprising therefore that these models are unable to extract as much information from the dataset as others, and consequently have a worse performance. One puzzling finding is the significance of the constant term in the ordinal preference models. Given that the states compared are randomly swapped, there should be no obvious preference for choosing the first or the second state in a comparison. Indeed for the original Exhaustive model, only 49.9% of responses selected the first state, whilst 50.1% of responses selected the second state. However, the constant terms suggest that the first state is typically preferred. Given that none of the independent variables (after switching) had significant means, there is no clear justification for a constant term. Removing the constant term from the regression makes no difference to any of the estimated coefficients to two decimal places. In the constant difference models, the constant term is insignificant except in the case of the Exhaustive model. Rather than suggesting poor performance of the other models (at it is unlikely to have an impact), this may instead suggest a problem with the general method. Here, independence of irrelevant of alternatives is assumed to obtain almost eight times the number of data points as used in other models and this larger sample size allows more items to be considered and may exaggerate significance. We considered using a random ranking-based model like Random 1 or Random 2 as our preferred ordinal preference model for a related concern that the Exhaustive model simply extracts too much data from limited preferences. Overall, the VAS Levels regression outperformed the cardinal differences regression vs Full Health. The VAS Levels regression considered disutility, as a loss against full health. However, the cardinal difference regression appears to do the same thing considering a difference versus full health. The former outperformed the latter for two reasons firstly, taking differences reduces the sample size instead of having n observations from an individual we have only (n-1) observations, and so less information to estimate the underlying regression. The second reason is structural: the constant in the levels regression is informative because it functions as an N2 term (in a similar way to the N3 term). Here, any deviation from full health starts at 0.84 (i.e ) plus whatever additional decrement is suggested by the coefficients. In the cardinal difference regressions, this difference is lost and hence is not measured as this role is significant in the levels regression, the fit of the model is poorer without it, and this is reflected in the results. Conclusions

15 15 This paper has compared alternative analyses for different ordinal preferences over health states and cardinal differences between health states, alongside a regression estimating the levels of health. We have identified preferred models for the ordinal preference and cardinal difference states. In contrast to previous studies we have found that ordinal preference models appear to give different results to cardinal data. The similarly severe states considered in the MVH study may have contributed to this. Unless similarly close states can be avoided (e.g. in experimental design), then exploding a ranked list of states for use in logit models appears unwise. Similarly, we have concerns about the reliance of an exhaustive logit on independence of irrelevant alternatives. McCabe et al found this assumption to be violated, and we have additional concerns over possibly exaggerated significance. Given that the ordinal preference data performs worse than the cardinal difference and levels regression, it seems relatively clear that: (1) VAS contains at least some relevant and useful cardinal data and (2) ignoring such data worsens performance of the resulting measures. A more general issue relates to whether ordinal preference data should be used in valuation tasks. There are a variety of different means by which ordinal preference data could be used and this paper has not considered the full variety of methods available, with DCE and/or Best-Worst both alternative options (see for example, Ryan et al, 2001). However, in standard valuation settings, it is likely that rank data will be elicited by post and based on tasks such as VAS rather than on more intensive SG or TTO data. Both Salomon and McCabe et al used ranking data based on more intensive methods and both found that the ordinal data obtained were adequate. This is not a guarantee that ranking data per se is adequate, and the findings here are to the contrary.

16 16 References Brazier, J. and McCabe, C Is there a case for using visual analogue scale valuations in CUA by Parkin and Devlin a response: Yes there is a case, but what does it add to ordinal data? Health Economics. 16: Dolan, P., Gudex, C., Kind P., Williams, A The measurement and valuation of health: First report on the main survey. Centre for Health Economics, University of York: York Dolan, P., and Roberts, J Modelling Valuations for Eq-5d Health States: An Alternative Model Using Differences in Valuations. Medical Care 40(5): Johannesson, M., Jonsson, B., Karlsson, G Outcome measurement in economic evaluation. Health Economics. 5: McCabe, C., Brazier, J., Gilks, P., Tsuchiya, A., Roberts, J., O Hagan, A., Stevens, K Using rank data to estimate health state utility models. Journal of Health Economics. 25: McCabe, C., Stevens, K., Roberts, J., Brazier, J.E. 2005a. Health state valuations for the Health Utilties Index Mark 2 descriptive system: result from a UK valuable survey. Health Economics. 14: McCabe, C., Stevens, K., Brazier, J.E. 2005b. Utility values for Health Utilties Index Mark 2: An empirical assessment of alternative mapping functions. Medical Care. 43: Parducci, A., and Weddell, D.H The category effect with rating scales: number of categories, number of stimuli, and method of presentation. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 12: Parkin, D. and Devlin, N Is there a case for using visual analogue scale valuations in costutility analysis? Health Economics. 15: Roberts, J. and Dolan, P To what extent do people prefer health states with higher values? A note on evidence from the EQ-5D valuation set. Health Economics. 13:

17 17 Robinson, A., Loomes, G., and Jones-Lee, M Visual Analog Scales, Standard Gambles, and Relative Risk Aversion. Medical Decision Making 21:17-27 Ryan, M., Scott, D.A., Reeves, C., Bate, A., van Teijlingen, E.R., Russell, E.M., Napper, M., Robb, C.M Eliciting public preferences for health care: a systematic review of techniques. Health Technology Assessment; 5(5): Salomon, J.A Reconsidering the use of rankings in the valuation of health states: a model for estimating cardinal values from ordinal data. Population Health Metrics. 1:12. (accessed ) Schwartz, A Rating scales in context. Medical Decision Making 18:236. Torrance G.W., Feeny, D.H., Furlong Visual analogue scales; do they have a role in the measurement of preferences for health states? Medical Decision Making. 21:

To what extent do people prefer health states with higher values? A note on evidence from the EQ-5D valuation set

To what extent do people prefer health states with higher values? A note on evidence from the EQ-5D valuation set HEALTH ECONOMICS HEALTH ECONOMICS LETTERS Health Econ. 13: 733 737 (2004) Published online 15 December 2003 in Wiley InterScience (www.interscience.wiley.com). DOI:10.1002/hec.875 To what extent do people

More information

Using Discrete Choice Experiments with duration to model EQ-5D-5L health state preferences: Testing experimental design strategies

Using Discrete Choice Experiments with duration to model EQ-5D-5L health state preferences: Testing experimental design strategies Using Discrete Choice Experiments with duration to model EQ-5D-5L health state preferences: Testing experimental design strategies Brendan Mulhern 1,2 (MRes), Nick Bansback 3 (PhD), Arne Risa Hole 4 (PhD),

More information

Time to tweak the TTO: results from a comparison of alternative specifications of the TTO

Time to tweak the TTO: results from a comparison of alternative specifications of the TTO Eur J Health Econ (2013) 14 (Suppl 1):S43 S51 DOI 10.1007/s10198-013-0507-y ORIGINAL PAPER Time to tweak the TTO: results from a comparison of alternative specifications of the TTO Matthijs M. Versteegh

More information

How is the most severe health state being valued by the general population?

How is the most severe health state being valued by the general population? Gandhi et al. Health and Quality of Life Outcomes 2014, 12:161 RESEARCH Open Access How is the most severe health state being valued by the general population? Mihir Gandhi 1,2,3*, Julian Thumboo 4,5,

More information

NICE DSU TECHNICAL SUPPORT DOCUMENT 8: AN INTRODUCTION TO THE MEASUREMENT AND VALUATION OF HEALTH FOR NICE SUBMISSIONS

NICE DSU TECHNICAL SUPPORT DOCUMENT 8: AN INTRODUCTION TO THE MEASUREMENT AND VALUATION OF HEALTH FOR NICE SUBMISSIONS NICE DSU TECHNICAL SUPPORT DOCUMENT 8: AN INTRODUCTION TO THE MEASUREMENT AND VALUATION OF HEALTH FOR NICE SUBMISSIONS REPORT BY THE DECISION SUPPORT UNIT August 2011 John Brazier 1 and Louise Longworth

More information

LIHS Mini Master Class

LIHS Mini Master Class Alexandru Nicusor Matei 2013 CC BY-NC-ND 2.0 Measurement and valuation of health using QALYS John O Dwyer Academic Unit of Health Economics John O Dwyer University of Leeds 2015. This work is made available

More information

Kelvin Chan Feb 10, 2015

Kelvin Chan Feb 10, 2015 Underestimation of Variance of Predicted Mean Health Utilities Derived from Multi- Attribute Utility Instruments: The Use of Multiple Imputation as a Potential Solution. Kelvin Chan Feb 10, 2015 Outline

More information

Study Protocol: Comparison of Inconsistency between Time Trade Off and Discrete Choice Experiments in EQ-5D-3 L Health State Valuations

Study Protocol: Comparison of Inconsistency between Time Trade Off and Discrete Choice Experiments in EQ-5D-3 L Health State Valuations Study Protocol: Comparison of Inconsistency between Time Trade Off and Discrete Choice Experiments in EQ-5D-3 L Health State Valuations Author Kularatna, Sanjeewa, Byrnes, Joshua, Scuffham, Paul Published

More information

Japan Journal of Medicine

Japan Journal of Medicine 29 Japan Journal of Medicine 28; (6): 29-296. doi:.3488/jjm.3 Research article An International comparative Study on EuroQol-5-Dimension Questionnaire (EQ-5D) tariff scores between the and Japan Tsuguo

More information

Time Trade-Off and Ranking Exercises Are Sensitive to Different Dimensions of EQ-5D Health States

Time Trade-Off and Ranking Exercises Are Sensitive to Different Dimensions of EQ-5D Health States VALUE IN HEALTH 15 (2012) 777 782 Available online at www.sciencedirect.com journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jval Time Trade-Off and Ranking Exercises Are Sensitive to Different Dimensions of

More information

EuroQol Working Paper Series

EuroQol Working Paper Series EuroQol Working Paper Series Number 15001 June 2015 ORIGINAL RESEARCH An empirical study of two alternative comparators for use in time trade-off studies Koonal K. Shah 1 Brendan Mulhern 2 Louise Longworth

More information

Is there a case for using Visual Analogue Scale valuations in Cost- Utility Analysis?

Is there a case for using Visual Analogue Scale valuations in Cost- Utility Analysis? Is there a case for using Visual Analogue Scale valuations in Cost- Utility Analysis? Abstract David Parkin and Nancy Devlin City Health Economics Centre, City University, London Paper presented to the

More information

Learning Effects in Time Trade-Off Based Valuation of EQ-5D Health States

Learning Effects in Time Trade-Off Based Valuation of EQ-5D Health States Available online at www.sciencedirect.com journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jval Learning Effects in Time Trade-Off Based Valuation of EQ-5D Health States Liv Ariane Augestad, MD 1, *, Kim Rand-Hendriksen,

More information

Is EQ-5D-5L Better Than EQ-5D-3L? A Head-to-Head Comparison of Descriptive Systems and Value Sets from Seven Countries

Is EQ-5D-5L Better Than EQ-5D-3L? A Head-to-Head Comparison of Descriptive Systems and Value Sets from Seven Countries PharmacoEconomics (2018) 36:675 697 https://doi.org/10.1007/s40273-018-0623-8 ORIGINAL RESEARCH ARTICLE Is EQ-5D- Better Than EQ-5D-? A Head-to-Head Comparison of Descriptive Systems and Value Sets from

More information

This is a repository copy of Estimating an EQ-5D population value set: the case of Japan.

This is a repository copy of Estimating an EQ-5D population value set: the case of Japan. This is a repository copy of Estimating an EQ-5D population value set: the case of Japan. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/105364/ Version: Accepted Version

More information

Waiting times. Deriving utility weights for the EQ-5D-5L

Waiting times. Deriving utility weights for the EQ-5D-5L i Deriving utility weights for the EQ-5D-5L using a discrete choice experiment Working Paper 2012/01 January 2012 A report by the Centre for Health Economics Research and Evaluation ii About CHERE CHERE

More information

Health Economics & Decision Science (HEDS) Discussion Paper Series

Health Economics & Decision Science (HEDS) Discussion Paper Series School of Health And Related Research Health Economics & Decision Science (HEDS) Discussion Paper Series Valuing Health-Related Quality of Life: An EQ-5D-5L Value Set for England Authors: Nancy Devlin,

More information

NIH Public Access Author Manuscript J Clin Epidemiol. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2010 March 1.

NIH Public Access Author Manuscript J Clin Epidemiol. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2010 March 1. NIH Public Access Author Manuscript Published in final edited form as: J Clin Epidemiol. 2009 March ; 62(3): 296 305. doi:10.1016/j.jclinepi.2008.07.002. Keep it simple: Ranking health states yields values

More information

Keep it simple: Ranking health states yields values similar to cardinal measurement approaches

Keep it simple: Ranking health states yields values similar to cardinal measurement approaches Journal of Clinical Epidemiology 62 (2009) 296e305 Keep it simple: Ranking health states yields values similar to cardinal measurement approaches Benjamin M. Craig a, *, Jan J.V. Busschbach b, Joshua A.

More information

To what extent can we explain time trade-off values from other information about respondents?

To what extent can we explain time trade-off values from other information about respondents? Social Science & Medicine 54 (2002) 919 929 To what extent can we explain time trade-off values from other information about respondents? Paul Dolan a,b, *, Jennifer Roberts c a Sheffield Health Economics

More information

Department of Economics

Department of Economics Department of Economics Does the value of quality of life depend on duration? Nancy Devlin 1 Office of Health Economics Aki Tsuchiya University of Sheffield Ken Buckingham University of Otago Carl Tilling

More information

How to Measure and Value Health Benefits to Facilitate Priority Setting for Pediatric Population? Development and Application Issues.

How to Measure and Value Health Benefits to Facilitate Priority Setting for Pediatric Population? Development and Application Issues. IP12 How to Measure and Value Health Benefits to Facilitate Priority Setting for Pediatric Population? Development and Application Issues 17:00 18:00 September 10 1 Speakers Gang Chen Ruoyan Gai Nan Luo

More information

This is a repository copy of The estimation of a preference-based measure of health from the SF-36.

This is a repository copy of The estimation of a preference-based measure of health from the SF-36. This is a repository copy of The estimation of a preference-based measure of health from the SF-36. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/474/ Article: Brazier,

More information

Comparison of Value Set Based on DCE and/or TTO Data: Scoring for EQ-5D-5L Health States in Japan

Comparison of Value Set Based on DCE and/or TTO Data: Scoring for EQ-5D-5L Health States in Japan VALUE IN HEALTH 19 (2016) 648 654 Available online at www.sciencedirect.com journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jval Preference-Based Assessments Comparison of Value Set Based on DCE and/or TTO Data:

More information

HEDS Discussion Paper 05/05

HEDS Discussion Paper 05/05 HEDS Discussion Paper 05/05 Disclaimer: This is a Discussion Paper produced and published by the Health Economics and Decision Science (HEDS) Section at the School of Health and Related Research (ScHARR),

More information

Comparing the UK EQ-5D-3L and English EQ-5D-5L value sets

Comparing the UK EQ-5D-3L and English EQ-5D-5L value sets Comparing the UK EQ-5D-3L and English EQ-5D-5L value sets Working Paper 2017/01 March 2017 A report by the Centre for Health Economics Research and Evaluation This CHERE Working Paper also has been published

More information

Measuring Quality of Life at the Centre for Health Economics

Measuring Quality of Life at the Centre for Health Economics Research Paper 2009 (41) Measuring Quality of Life at the Centre for Health Economics Description of instruments, interview props and their administration Angelo Iezzi Research Fellow Centre for Health

More information

A comparison of injured patient and general population valuations of EQ-5D health states for New Zealand

A comparison of injured patient and general population valuations of EQ-5D health states for New Zealand Wilson et al. Health and Quality of Life Outcomes 2014, 12:21 RESEARCH Open Access A comparison of injured patient and general valuations of EQ-5D health states for New Zealand Ross Wilson 1, Paul Hansen

More information

A new method of measuring how much anterior tooth alignment means to adolescents

A new method of measuring how much anterior tooth alignment means to adolescents European Journal of Orthodontics 21 (1999) 299 305 1999 European Orthodontic Society A new method of measuring how much anterior tooth alignment means to adolescents D. Fox, E. J. Kay and K. O Brien Department

More information

Economic evaluation of end stage renal disease treatment Ardine de Wit G, Ramsteijn P G, de Charro F T

Economic evaluation of end stage renal disease treatment Ardine de Wit G, Ramsteijn P G, de Charro F T Economic evaluation of end stage renal disease treatment Ardine de Wit G, Ramsteijn P G, de Charro F T Record Status This is a critical abstract of an economic evaluation that meets the criteria for inclusion

More information

15D: Strengths, weaknesses and future development

15D: Strengths, weaknesses and future development 15D: Strengths, weaknesses and future development Harri Sintonen University of Helsinki and FinOHTA Definition of health-related quality of life HRQoL instruments usually try, as does the 15D, to cover

More information

Analysis of Confidence Rating Pilot Data: Executive Summary for the UKCAT Board

Analysis of Confidence Rating Pilot Data: Executive Summary for the UKCAT Board Analysis of Confidence Rating Pilot Data: Executive Summary for the UKCAT Board Paul Tiffin & Lewis Paton University of York Background Self-confidence may be the best non-cognitive predictor of future

More information

A panel data comparison of two commonly-used health-related quality of life instruments

A panel data comparison of two commonly-used health-related quality of life instruments A panel data comparison of two commonly-used health-related quality of life instruments Zachary Gerring* 1 and Jaikishan Desai 1 Abstract Economic evaluations of health interventions require measuring

More information

Color naming and color matching: A reply to Kuehni and Hardin

Color naming and color matching: A reply to Kuehni and Hardin 1 Color naming and color matching: A reply to Kuehni and Hardin Pendaran Roberts & Kelly Schmidtke Forthcoming in Review of Philosophy and Psychology. The final publication is available at Springer via

More information

11/18/2013. Correlational Research. Correlational Designs. Why Use a Correlational Design? CORRELATIONAL RESEARCH STUDIES

11/18/2013. Correlational Research. Correlational Designs. Why Use a Correlational Design? CORRELATIONAL RESEARCH STUDIES Correlational Research Correlational Designs Correlational research is used to describe the relationship between two or more naturally occurring variables. Is age related to political conservativism? Are

More information

Is there a case for using visual analogue scale valuations in cost-utility analysis?

Is there a case for using visual analogue scale valuations in cost-utility analysis? HEALTH ECONOMICS Health Econ. 15: 653 664 (2006) Published online 24 February 2006 in Wiley InterScience (www.interscience.wiley.com). DOI:10.1002/hec.1086 Is there a case for using visual analogue scale

More information

Exploring the reference point in prospect theory

Exploring the reference point in prospect theory 3 Exploring the reference point in prospect theory Gambles for length of life Exploring the reference point in prospect theory: Gambles for length of life. S.M.C. van Osch, W.B. van den Hout, A.M. Stiggelbout

More information

Experience-based VAS values for EQ-5D-3L health states in a national general population health survey in China

Experience-based VAS values for EQ-5D-3L health states in a national general population health survey in China Qual Life Res (2015) 24:693 703 DOI 10.1007/s11136-014-0793-6 Experience-based VAS values for EQ-5D-3L health states in a national general population health survey in China Sun Sun Jiaying Chen Paul Kind

More information

DRAFT (Final) Concept Paper On choosing appropriate estimands and defining sensitivity analyses in confirmatory clinical trials

DRAFT (Final) Concept Paper On choosing appropriate estimands and defining sensitivity analyses in confirmatory clinical trials DRAFT (Final) Concept Paper On choosing appropriate estimands and defining sensitivity analyses in confirmatory clinical trials EFSPI Comments Page General Priority (H/M/L) Comment The concept to develop

More information

Effect of Choice Set on Valuation of Risky Prospects

Effect of Choice Set on Valuation of Risky Prospects Effect of Choice Set on Valuation of Risky Prospects Neil Stewart (neil.stewart@warwick.ac.uk) Nick Chater (nick.chater@warwick.ac.uk) Henry P. Stott (hstott@owc.com) Department of Psychology, University

More information

Statistics is the science of collecting, organizing, presenting, analyzing, and interpreting data to assist in making effective decisions

Statistics is the science of collecting, organizing, presenting, analyzing, and interpreting data to assist in making effective decisions Readings: OpenStax Textbook - Chapters 1 5 (online) Appendix D & E (online) Plous - Chapters 1, 5, 6, 13 (online) Introductory comments Describe how familiarity with statistical methods can - be associated

More information

Population Health Metrics

Population Health Metrics Population Health Metrics BioMed Central Research The episodic random utility model unifies time trade-off and discrete choice approaches in health state valuation Benjamin M Craig* 1, and Jan JV Busschbach

More information

Statistics is the science of collecting, organizing, presenting, analyzing, and interpreting data to assist in making effective decisions

Statistics is the science of collecting, organizing, presenting, analyzing, and interpreting data to assist in making effective decisions Readings: OpenStax Textbook - Chapters 1 5 (online) Appendix D & E (online) Plous - Chapters 1, 5, 6, 13 (online) Introductory comments Describe how familiarity with statistical methods can - be associated

More information

This is a repository copy of A comparison of the EQ-5D and the SF-6D across seven patient groups.

This is a repository copy of A comparison of the EQ-5D and the SF-6D across seven patient groups. This is a repository copy of A comparison of the EQ-5D and the SF-6D across seven patient groups. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/279/ Article: Brazier, J.E.,

More information

Title: A new statistical test for trends: establishing the properties of a test for repeated binomial observations on a set of items

Title: A new statistical test for trends: establishing the properties of a test for repeated binomial observations on a set of items Title: A new statistical test for trends: establishing the properties of a test for repeated binomial observations on a set of items Introduction Many studies of therapies with single subjects involve

More information

Measurement and meaningfulness in Decision Modeling

Measurement and meaningfulness in Decision Modeling Measurement and meaningfulness in Decision Modeling Brice Mayag University Paris Dauphine LAMSADE FRANCE Chapter 2 Brice Mayag (LAMSADE) Measurement theory and meaningfulness Chapter 2 1 / 47 Outline 1

More information

ISPOR 5th Latin America Conference. Minas Gerais - Brazil EQ-5D Research. Kenya Noronha CEDEPLAR/UFMG. ISPOR 5th Latin America Conference

ISPOR 5th Latin America Conference. Minas Gerais - Brazil EQ-5D Research. Kenya Noronha CEDEPLAR/UFMG. ISPOR 5th Latin America Conference ISPOR 5th Latin America Conference Minas Gerais - Brazil EQ-5D Research Kenya Noronha CEDEPLAR/UFMG W15: EQ-5D: EL MÉTODO BÁSICO PARA LA MEDICIÓN Y VALORACIÓN DE LA SALUD EN AMÉRICA LATINA Santiago, Chile

More information

Condition-Specific Preference-Based Measures: Benefit or Burden?

Condition-Specific Preference-Based Measures: Benefit or Burden? Available online at www.sciencedirect.com journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jval Preference-Based Assessments Condition-Specific Preference-Based Measures: Benefit or Burden? Matthijs M. Versteegh,

More information

Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game

Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game Ivaylo Vlaev (ivaylo.vlaev@psy.ox.ac.uk) Department of Experimental Psychology, University of Oxford, Oxford, OX1

More information

University of Groningen

University of Groningen University of Groningen Dutch Tariff for the Five-Level Version of EQ-5D Versteegh, Matthijs M.; Vermeulen, Karin M.; Evers, Silvia M. A. A.; de Wit, G. Ardine; Prenger, Rilana; Stolk, Elly A. Published

More information

Technical Specifications

Technical Specifications Technical Specifications In order to provide summary information across a set of exercises, all tests must employ some form of scoring models. The most familiar of these scoring models is the one typically

More information

Research and Evaluation Methodology Program, School of Human Development and Organizational Studies in Education, University of Florida

Research and Evaluation Methodology Program, School of Human Development and Organizational Studies in Education, University of Florida Vol. 2 (1), pp. 22-39, Jan, 2015 http://www.ijate.net e-issn: 2148-7456 IJATE A Comparison of Logistic Regression Models for Dif Detection in Polytomous Items: The Effect of Small Sample Sizes and Non-Normality

More information

Mapping QLQ-C30, HAQ, and MSIS-29 on EQ-5D

Mapping QLQ-C30, HAQ, and MSIS-29 on EQ-5D HEALTH-RELATED QUALITY OF LIFE Mapping QLQ-C30, HAQ, and MSIS-29 on EQ-5D Matthijs M. Versteegh, MA, Annemieke Leunis, MSc, Jolanda J. Luime, PhD, Mike Boggild, MD, MRCP, Carin A. Uyl-de Groot, PhD, Elly

More information

Tails from the Peak District: Adjusted Limited Dependent Variable Mixture Models of EQ-5D Questionnaire Health State Utility Values

Tails from the Peak District: Adjusted Limited Dependent Variable Mixture Models of EQ-5D Questionnaire Health State Utility Values VALUE IN HEALTH 15 (01) 550 561 Available online at www.sciencedirect.com journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jval Tails from the Peak District: Adjusted Limited Dependent Variable Mixture Models

More information

University of Bristol - Explore Bristol Research. Publisher's PDF, also known as Version of record

University of Bristol - Explore Bristol Research. Publisher's PDF, also known as Version of record Al-Janabi, H., Flynn, T. N., Peters, T. J., Bryan, S., & Coast, J. (2015). Testretest reliability of capability measurement in the UK general population. Health Economics, 24(5), 625-30..3100 Publisher's

More information

Health Economics Working Paper Series HEWPS Number: Exploring differences between TTO and direct choice in the valuation of health states

Health Economics Working Paper Series HEWPS Number: Exploring differences between TTO and direct choice in the valuation of health states ISSN: 2052-9368 Health Economics Working Paper Series HEWPS Number: 201502 Exploring differences between TTO and direct choice in the valuation of health states Angela Robinson, Anne Spencer, Jose Luis

More information

This is a repository copy of Deriving a preference-based measure for cancer using the EORTC QLQ-C30.

This is a repository copy of Deriving a preference-based measure for cancer using the EORTC QLQ-C30. This is a repository copy of Deriving a preference-based measure for cancer using the EORTC QLQ-C30. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/10872/ Monograph: Rowen,

More information

Regression Discontinuity Analysis

Regression Discontinuity Analysis Regression Discontinuity Analysis A researcher wants to determine whether tutoring underachieving middle school students improves their math grades. Another wonders whether providing financial aid to low-income

More information

Valuing Health-Related Quality of Life A Review of Health State Valuation Techniques

Valuing Health-Related Quality of Life A Review of Health State Valuation Techniques REVIEW ARTICLE Pharmacoeconomics 2000 Feb; 17 (2): 151-165 1170-7690/00/0002-0151/$20.00/0 Adis International Limited. All rights reserved. Valuing Health-Related Quality of Life A Review of Health State

More information

Valuation of the SF-6D Health States Is Feasible, Acceptable, Reliable, and Valid in a Chinese Population

Valuation of the SF-6D Health States Is Feasible, Acceptable, Reliable, and Valid in a Chinese Population Volume 11 Number 2 2008 VALUE IN HEALTH Valuation of the SF-6D Health States Is Feasible, Acceptable, Reliable, and Valid in a Chinese Population Cindy L. K. Lam, MBBS, MD, FRCGP, FHKAM (Family Medicine),

More information

HEALTH ECONOMICS GROUP Faculty of Medicine and Health Norwich Medical School

HEALTH ECONOMICS GROUP Faculty of Medicine and Health Norwich Medical School HEALTH ECONOMICS GROUP Faculty of Medicine and Health Norwich Medical School The use of risk-based discrete choice experiments to capture preferences over health states Angela Robinson 1, Anne Spencer

More information

o^ &&cvi AL Perceptual and Motor Skills, 1965, 20, Southern Universities Press 1965

o^ &&cvi AL Perceptual and Motor Skills, 1965, 20, Southern Universities Press 1965 Ml 3 Hi o^ &&cvi AL 44755 Perceptual and Motor Skills, 1965, 20, 311-316. Southern Universities Press 1965 m CONFIDENCE RATINGS AND LEVEL OF PERFORMANCE ON A JUDGMENTAL TASK 1 RAYMOND S. NICKERSON AND

More information

A Comparison of Several Goodness-of-Fit Statistics

A Comparison of Several Goodness-of-Fit Statistics A Comparison of Several Goodness-of-Fit Statistics Robert L. McKinley The University of Toledo Craig N. Mills Educational Testing Service A study was conducted to evaluate four goodnessof-fit procedures

More information

Mantel-Haenszel Procedures for Detecting Differential Item Functioning

Mantel-Haenszel Procedures for Detecting Differential Item Functioning A Comparison of Logistic Regression and Mantel-Haenszel Procedures for Detecting Differential Item Functioning H. Jane Rogers, Teachers College, Columbia University Hariharan Swaminathan, University of

More information

Citation for published version (APA): Ebbes, P. (2004). Latent instrumental variables: a new approach to solve for endogeneity s.n.

Citation for published version (APA): Ebbes, P. (2004). Latent instrumental variables: a new approach to solve for endogeneity s.n. University of Groningen Latent instrumental variables Ebbes, P. IMPORTANT NOTE: You are advised to consult the publisher's version (publisher's PDF) if you wish to cite from it. Please check the document

More information

Some Thoughts on the Principle of Revealed Preference 1

Some Thoughts on the Principle of Revealed Preference 1 Some Thoughts on the Principle of Revealed Preference 1 Ariel Rubinstein School of Economics, Tel Aviv University and Department of Economics, New York University and Yuval Salant Graduate School of Business,

More information

The Impact of Relative Standards on the Propensity to Disclose. Alessandro Acquisti, Leslie K. John, George Loewenstein WEB APPENDIX

The Impact of Relative Standards on the Propensity to Disclose. Alessandro Acquisti, Leslie K. John, George Loewenstein WEB APPENDIX The Impact of Relative Standards on the Propensity to Disclose Alessandro Acquisti, Leslie K. John, George Loewenstein WEB APPENDIX 2 Web Appendix A: Panel data estimation approach As noted in the main

More information

UNIVERSITY OF THE FREE STATE DEPARTMENT OF COMPUTER SCIENCE AND INFORMATICS CSIS6813 MODULE TEST 2

UNIVERSITY OF THE FREE STATE DEPARTMENT OF COMPUTER SCIENCE AND INFORMATICS CSIS6813 MODULE TEST 2 UNIVERSITY OF THE FREE STATE DEPARTMENT OF COMPUTER SCIENCE AND INFORMATICS CSIS6813 MODULE TEST 2 DATE: 3 May 2017 MARKS: 75 ASSESSOR: Prof PJ Blignaut MODERATOR: Prof C de Villiers (UP) TIME: 2 hours

More information

The role of non-transparent matching methods in avoiding preference reversals in the evaluation of health outcomes. Fernando I.

The role of non-transparent matching methods in avoiding preference reversals in the evaluation of health outcomes. Fernando I. The role of non-transparent matching methods in avoiding preference reversals in the evaluation of health outcomes Fernando I. Sánchez Martínez Universidad de Murcia, Spain Jose Luis Pinto Prades* Glasgow

More information

Issues Surrounding the Normalization and Standardisation of Skin Conductance Responses (SCRs).

Issues Surrounding the Normalization and Standardisation of Skin Conductance Responses (SCRs). Issues Surrounding the Normalization and Standardisation of Skin Conductance Responses (SCRs). Jason J. Braithwaite {Behavioural Brain Sciences Centre, School of Psychology, University of Birmingham, UK}

More information

August 29, Introduction and Overview

August 29, Introduction and Overview August 29, 2018 Introduction and Overview Why are we here? Haavelmo(1944): to become master of the happenings of real life. Theoretical models are necessary tools in our attempts to understand and explain

More information

Measuring and Assessing Study Quality

Measuring and Assessing Study Quality Measuring and Assessing Study Quality Jeff Valentine, PhD Co-Chair, Campbell Collaboration Training Group & Associate Professor, College of Education and Human Development, University of Louisville Why

More information

Version No. 7 Date: July Please send comments or suggestions on this glossary to

Version No. 7 Date: July Please send comments or suggestions on this glossary to Impact Evaluation Glossary Version No. 7 Date: July 2012 Please send comments or suggestions on this glossary to 3ie@3ieimpact.org. Recommended citation: 3ie (2012) 3ie impact evaluation glossary. International

More information

Adaptive Testing With the Multi-Unidimensional Pairwise Preference Model Stephen Stark University of South Florida

Adaptive Testing With the Multi-Unidimensional Pairwise Preference Model Stephen Stark University of South Florida Adaptive Testing With the Multi-Unidimensional Pairwise Preference Model Stephen Stark University of South Florida and Oleksandr S. Chernyshenko University of Canterbury Presented at the New CAT Models

More information

Published online: 10 January 2015 The Author(s) This article is published with open access at Springerlink.com

Published online: 10 January 2015 The Author(s) This article is published with open access at Springerlink.com J Happiness Stud (2016) 17:833 873 DOI 10.1007/s10902-014-9611-7 RESEARCH PAPER Subjective Well-Being and Its Association with Subjective Health Status, Age, Sex, Region, and Socio-economic Characteristics

More information

11/24/2017. Do not imply a cause-and-effect relationship

11/24/2017. Do not imply a cause-and-effect relationship Correlational research is used to describe the relationship between two or more naturally occurring variables. Is age related to political conservativism? Are highly extraverted people less afraid of rejection

More information

Lecturer: Rob van der Willigen 11/9/08

Lecturer: Rob van der Willigen 11/9/08 Auditory Perception - Detection versus Discrimination - Localization versus Discrimination - - Electrophysiological Measurements Psychophysical Measurements Three Approaches to Researching Audition physiology

More information

Reliability, validity, and all that jazz

Reliability, validity, and all that jazz Reliability, validity, and all that jazz Dylan Wiliam King s College London Published in Education 3-13, 29 (3) pp. 17-21 (2001) Introduction No measuring instrument is perfect. If we use a thermometer

More information

Module 14: Missing Data Concepts

Module 14: Missing Data Concepts Module 14: Missing Data Concepts Jonathan Bartlett & James Carpenter London School of Hygiene & Tropical Medicine Supported by ESRC grant RES 189-25-0103 and MRC grant G0900724 Pre-requisites Module 3

More information

Msc in Health Economics, Policy and Law. Institute of Health Policy and Management. Erasmus University Rotterdam. Master Thesis

Msc in Health Economics, Policy and Law. Institute of Health Policy and Management. Erasmus University Rotterdam. Master Thesis Msc in Health Economics, Policy and Law Institute of Health Policy and Management Erasmus University Rotterdam Master Thesis QALY MODEL: Test of Utility Independence when health varies over time Name:

More information

Adam J. Oliver. The internal consistency of the standard gamble : tests after adjusting for prospect theory

Adam J. Oliver. The internal consistency of the standard gamble : tests after adjusting for prospect theory LSE Research Online Article (refereed) Adam J. Oliver The internal consistency of the standard gamble : tests after adjusting for prospect theory Originally published in Journal of health economics, 22

More information

Lecturer: Rob van der Willigen 11/9/08

Lecturer: Rob van der Willigen 11/9/08 Auditory Perception - Detection versus Discrimination - Localization versus Discrimination - Electrophysiological Measurements - Psychophysical Measurements 1 Three Approaches to Researching Audition physiology

More information

Cost-effectiveness ratios are commonly used to

Cost-effectiveness ratios are commonly used to ... HEALTH ECONOMICS... Application of Cost-Effectiveness Analysis to Multiple Products: A Practical Guide Mohan V. Bala, PhD; and Gary A. Zarkin, PhD The appropriate interpretation of cost-effectiveness

More information

Impact of Chronic Liver Disease and Cirrhosis on Health Utilities Using SF-6D and the Health Utility Index

Impact of Chronic Liver Disease and Cirrhosis on Health Utilities Using SF-6D and the Health Utility Index LIVER TRANSPLANTATION 14:321-326, 2008 ORIGINAL ARTICLE Impact of Chronic Liver Disease and Cirrhosis on Health Utilities Using SF-6D and the Health Utility Index Amy A. Dan, 1,2 Jillian B. Kallman, 1,2

More information

Context of Best Subset Regression

Context of Best Subset Regression Estimation of the Squared Cross-Validity Coefficient in the Context of Best Subset Regression Eugene Kennedy South Carolina Department of Education A monte carlo study was conducted to examine the performance

More information

This is a repository copy of Using Conditioning on Observed Choices to Retrieve Individual-Specific Attribute Processing Strategies.

This is a repository copy of Using Conditioning on Observed Choices to Retrieve Individual-Specific Attribute Processing Strategies. This is a repository copy of Using Conditioning on Observed Choices to Retrieve Individual-Specific Attribute Processing Strategies. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/43604/

More information

Swedish experience-based value sets for EQ-5D health states

Swedish experience-based value sets for EQ-5D health states Qual Life Res (2014) 23:431 442 DOI 10.1007/s11136-013-0496-4 Swedish experience-based value sets for EQ-5D health states Kristina Burström Sun Sun Ulf-G Gerdtham Martin Henriksson Magnus Johannesson Lars-Åke

More information

Original Research Article Pain Quality of Life as Measured by Utilities

Original Research Article Pain Quality of Life as Measured by Utilities bs_bs_banner Pain Medicine 2014; 15: 865 870 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. REHABILITATION SECTION Original Research Article Pain Quality of Life as Measured by Utilities Sarah Wetherington, BS,* Laura Delong,

More information

Quality review of a proposed EQ- 5D-5L value set for England

Quality review of a proposed EQ- 5D-5L value set for England Quality review of a proposed EQ- 5D-5L value set for England October 2018 Authors: Mónica Hernández-Alava 1, Stephen Pudney 1 & Allan Wailoo 1 1 ScHARR, University of Sheffield 1 ACKNOWLEDGMENTS This research

More information

University of Groningen. Quantification of Health by Scaling Similarity Judgments Arons, Alexander M. M.; Krabbe, Paulus. Published in: PLoS ONE

University of Groningen. Quantification of Health by Scaling Similarity Judgments Arons, Alexander M. M.; Krabbe, Paulus. Published in: PLoS ONE University of Groningen Quantification of Health by Scaling Similarity Judgments Arons, Alexander M. M.; Krabbe, Paulus Published in: PLoS ONE DOI: 10.1371/journal.pone.0089091 IMPORTANT NOTE: You are

More information

Validity and reliability of measurements

Validity and reliability of measurements Validity and reliability of measurements 2 Validity and reliability of measurements 4 5 Components in a dataset Why bother (examples from research) What is reliability? What is validity? How should I treat

More information

METHODOLOGY FOR MEASURING HEALTH-STATE PREFERENCES-II: SCALING METHODS

METHODOLOGY FOR MEASURING HEALTH-STATE PREFERENCES-II: SCALING METHODS J Clin Epidemiol Vol. 42, No. 5, pp. 459471, 1989 Printed in Great Britain. All rights reserved 0895-4356/89 $3.00 + 0.00 Copyright 0 1989 Pergamon Press plc METHODOLOGY FOR MEASURING HEALTH-STATE PREFERENCES-II:

More information

Valuation of EQ-5D Health States in Poland: First TTO-Based Social Value Set in Central and Eastern Europevhe_

Valuation of EQ-5D Health States in Poland: First TTO-Based Social Value Set in Central and Eastern Europevhe_ Volume 13 Number 2 2010 VALUE IN HEALTH Valuation of EQ-5D Health States in Poland: First TTO-Based Social Value Set in Central and Eastern Europevhe_596 289..297 Dominik Golicki, MD, PhD, 1 Michał Jakubczyk,

More information

Where appropriate we have also made reference to the fair innings and end of life concepts.

Where appropriate we have also made reference to the fair innings and end of life concepts. Clarifying meanings of absolute and proportional with examples 1. Context There appeared to be some confusion at Value-Based Pricing Methods Group working party meeting on 19 th July around concept of

More information

Health care policy evaluation: empirical analysis of the restrictions implied by Quality Adjusted Life Years

Health care policy evaluation: empirical analysis of the restrictions implied by Quality Adjusted Life Years Health care policy evaluation: empirical analysis of the restrictions implied by Quality Adusted Life Years Rosalie Viney and Elizabeth Savage CHERE, University of Technology, Sydney Preliminary not for

More information

Using the EQ-5D index score as a predictor of outcomes in patients with type 2 diabetes.

Using the EQ-5D index score as a predictor of outcomes in patients with type 2 diabetes. Using the EQ-5D index score as a predictor of outcomes in patients with type 2 diabetes. WORK IN PROGRESS: PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE Status: In press with Medical Care Authors: Philip M. Clarke Ph.D 1,2 Alison

More information

25. EXPLAINING VALIDITYAND RELIABILITY

25. EXPLAINING VALIDITYAND RELIABILITY 25. EXPLAINING VALIDITYAND RELIABILITY "Validity" and "reliability" are ubiquitous terms in social science measurement. They are prominent in the APA "Standards" (1985) and earn chapters in test theory

More information

Teaching A Way of Implementing Statistical Methods for Ordinal Data to Researchers

Teaching A Way of Implementing Statistical Methods for Ordinal Data to Researchers Journal of Mathematics and System Science (01) 8-1 D DAVID PUBLISHING Teaching A Way of Implementing Statistical Methods for Ordinal Data to Researchers Elisabeth Svensson Department of Statistics, Örebro

More information

Validity and reliability of measurements

Validity and reliability of measurements Validity and reliability of measurements 2 3 Request: Intention to treat Intention to treat and per protocol dealing with cross-overs (ref Hulley 2013) For example: Patients who did not take/get the medication

More information

Centre for Health Economics

Centre for Health Economics Centre for Health Economics Working Paper 143 The Assessment of Quality of Life (AQoL) II Instrument The Effect of Deliberation and Alternative Utility Weights in a Multi-Attribute Utility Instrument Dr

More information