The Fiscal Impact of Raising Texas Alcohol Taxes

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Fiscal Impact of Raising Texas Alcohol Taxes"

Transcription

1 Texas Perspectives, Inc. The Fiscal Impact of Raising Texas Alcohol Taxes Presented to January 20, 2002 PAGE 1

2 The Fiscal Impact of Raising Alcohol Taxes in Texas. An Analysis by Texas Perspectives, Inc. MAJOR FINDINGS Bringing Texas beer and liquor taxes in line with the national average and raising the mixed beverage tax by one percent provides a win-win situation that would both increase state revenues and reduce state costs. Bringing Texas beer and liquor taxes in line with the national average and raising the mixed beverage tax by one percent would generate an estimated $91 million in new revenue for Texas state coffers in Alcohol (especially beer) is not an especially price sensitive commodity. In other words, higher alcohol prices do not generally result in substantial drops in consumption. As such, a modest increase in Texas alcohol taxes would generate significant new revenue. In addition to generating new revenue for state coffers, raising Texas alcohol taxes could lead to modest reductions in alcohol consumption and abuse, especially among under-aged youth and young adult drinkers who are typically more price sensitive. A one percent drop in demand for alcohol would yield an estimated positive state fiscal impact of nearly $59 million in This figure includes both direct (e.g., reduced spending on treatment, medical care) and indirect state benefits (e.g., increased productivity). The total fiscal impact of raising Texas alcohol taxes is conservatively estimated at $152 million in 2004 (this amount includes $91 million in new tax revenues plus $59 million in direct and indirect savings related to reduced levels of alcohol abuse). Bringing beer and liquor taxes in line with the national average and raising the mixed beverage tax by one percent would have a marginal impact on the cost of alcohol for Texas consumers. For example, doubling the state excise tax on beer to $12 per barrel would increase the average cost of a beer by only about 2.5 cents. If current trends continue, Texas taxpayers will face $5.81 billion in alcohol-abuse-related costs by 2004 the equivalent of $216 per person. Costs include direct state expenditures like PAGE 2

3 treatment costs, and more indirect costs like increased crime and lost productivity. PAGE 2

4 BACKGROUND Texas collects five alcohol taxes, three of which comprise the vast bulk of alcohol-related revenue to the state. Texas tax levels on alcohol are well below the national average. More than a decade has passed since the Texas Legislature last increased taxes related to alcohol. To restore the same real tax value of excise taxes established back in 1984, lawmakers would need to raise alcohol-related excise taxes by about 77 percent. Alcohol-related excise taxes generated about $520 million in revenue during 2000 representing only 2.1 percent of the state s total tax collections compared to 3.1 percent in 1985 (the year following the last increase in alcohol taxes). In fiscal year 2000, Texans paid an average of $25 per year in state alcohol taxes. The actual tax burden per resident is arguably lower since tourists and visitors pay a considerable amount of the tax. Overall, Texans consume five percent more alcohol per capita than residents in other states. TEXAS ALCOHOL TAXES TAX State Mixed Beverage State Liquor Tax State Beer Tax Note: TAX RATE & BASE 14% on permit holder gross receipts $2.40 per gallon (wholesale) $6.00 per barrel (wholesale) TAX RATES PER SERVING 70 cents per drink 2.7 cents per 1.5-oz serving 1.8 cents per single 12-oz beer. LAST TAX INCREASE COMPARISON WITH NATIONAL AVERAGE 1990 No corresponding federal tax % below national average % below national average The tax on airline and passenger train beverage sales, malt liquor and wine sales were not considered because of their relatively small fiscal impact. Alcohol sold at retail also is subject to the state 6.25% sales tax, and local levies.

5 Overview Taxes on the sale and/or consumption of alcohol are important to policymakers for at least two reasons. First, they have long been a reliable and significant source of revenue to fund government operations of all types. In the year 2000, for example, the State of Texas collected about $520 million through a variety of these alcohol taxes. Second, to the extent that higher prices lead to reduced consumption and/or abuse of alcohol, these taxes thus represent an additional policy variable for decision-makers interested in influencing a wide variety of social problems, such as the rising incidence of fetal alcohol syndrome, traffic accidents and fatalities, domestic and societal violence, underage drinking, labor market productivity effects, and the long-term health care costs of alcohol abuse. Amid rising concern over Texas fiscal status, policymakers are paying close attention to opportunities to both increase revenue and reduce costs. Raising alcohol taxes would appear to accomplish both. Since demand for alcohol appears to be relatively inelastic (i.e., not very price-sensitive), raising the effective price (which is the net effect of a tax increase) will yield only a modest reduction in consumption in the near term, meaning that a significant amount of additional tax revenue will generated. The following table illustrates, and is based on the assumption that beer and liquor taxes are brought in line with national averages while the gross receipts tax on mixed drinks is raised one percentage point. The results are enlightening; this seemingly marginal change in tax rates would net the State approximately $93 million in additional tax revenue in The Fiscal Impact of Increased Alcohol Taxes in 2004 CATEGORY EXCISE TAX IMPACT SALES TAX IMAPCT PRICE QUANTITY IMPLIED SAVINGS IN ABUSE-RELATED SPENDING Raising the Beer Tax 28% $32.1 million $2.0 million 0.87% -0.26% $43.3 million Raising the Liquor Tax 56% $26.2 million ($1.5 million) 3.28% -4.92% $12.9 million Raising the Mixed Drink Tax $32.7 million $1.7 million 1.18% -0.24% $2.6 million 5

6 One Percentage Point TOTALS $91.0 million $2.2 million 1.41% -1.28% $58.9 million Even the modest reductions in demand observed under this scenario yield an additional positive impact to the state budget in the form of reduced expenditures related to alcohol abuse. As has been well-documented, alcohol and substance abuse costs Texas billions of dollars annually; even the small drop in demand expected under this scenario would save the State an additional $58.9 million, putting the initial total annual fiscal impact in excess of $152 million. As a result, increasing alcohol taxes is one of the clearest win-win options presently available to policymakers, since, depending on consumer price-sensitivity, it either generates substantial tax revenue or causes a significant reduction in abuse-related costs. In either case, Texas is better off than under the current system. 6

7 Introduction Taxes on the sale and/or consumption of alcohol are important to policymakers for at least two reasons. First, they have long been a reliable and significant source of revenue to fund government operations of all types. In the year 2000, for example, the State of Texas collected about $520 million through a variety of these alcohol taxes. Although this amounted to only about 2.1 percent of the state s total tax collections last year, it still represents a substantial program funding source. Between 1980 and 2000, these collections increased at an average rate of almost $90,000 per month. The second principal reason for policy interest in these kinds of taxes is more recent in origin. Over the past two decades, economists have increasingly joined in the alcohol policy debate by observing that consumption and especially abuse of alcohol can be reduced through price increases. Taxes imposed by government agencies represent part of the final price to the consumer of alcoholic beverages. To the extent that higher prices lead to reduced consumption and/or abuse of alcohol, these taxes thus represent an additional policy variable for decisionmakers interested in influencing a wide variety of social problems, such as the rising incidence of fetal alcohol syndrome, traffic accidents and fatalities, domestic and societal violence, underage drinking, labor market productivity effects, and the long-term health care costs of alcohol abuse. The principal purpose of this report is to estimate the immediate, short-term fiscal impacts for the State of Texas of increased taxes on alcohol. The complexities involved in looking deeper into the future are well beyond the scope of this investigation. Nevertheless, we provide some discussion of the longer term adjustments that can be expected from increasing state taxes on alcohol, including not just tax revenue impacts but the potentially larger impacts on the costs of providing various public and private social services. The next section discusses the concept of price elasticity of demand for alcohol, and reviews some of the more significant empirical research in this area. This topic is relevant because price changes will typically lead to changes in the quantity 7

8 demanded of any product, including alcoholic beverages. Taxes are a part of the final price perceived by consumers, and if consumer sensitivity to price changes is high, tax increases could actually lead to decreases in tax revenues collected. As will be seen, this is not the case for Texas alcoholic beverages sales, at least not in the short run. Specific Texas alcohol taxes are then reviewed. Current and historic tax levels are reported and the historic collections from different taxes are presented. This establishes both the relative significance of each tax to state coffers and its relative and absolute contributions to the final price to consumers. The fact that existing state excise taxes represent a relatively small and decreasing part of the final price of alcoholic beverages is established, suggesting that tax increases would have comparatively modest impacts on final consumption levels. Consumption patterns and significant demographic factors in the State are then outlined. This provides additional data needed to both estimate and interpret the magnitude of short-run fiscal and other effects of alcohol tax increases. Forecasts of the short-run fiscal impacts of increasing three of these taxes are then provided. These forecasts show that tens of millions of additional dollars could be collected by this means. The reduction in average consumption levels associated with the tax hikes is then used to provide a rough estimate of how the long-term social costs of alcohol dependence and abuse could be affected. These estimates together show that alcohol excise taxes can be a win-win for policymakers; they can be effectively employed to concurrently increase state revenues and reduce state expenditures, and in a way that is almost surely efficient from the societal perspective. Price Elasticity of Demand for Alcohol When the price of any normal consumer good or service is increased, the typical response of consumers is to reduce the amount of that good or service that they purchase. Conversely, if prices decrease, they will typically purchase more. The actual changes in quantities demanded are a matter of considerable interest to the producers of those goods and 8

9 services, and for many goods this price sensitivity is also of great interest to shapers of public policy. Economists have developed a measure to reflect the degree of sensitivity of consumers to price changes: the price elasticity of demand. This measure is formally defined as the relative (or percent) change in quantity demanded divided by the relative (or percent) change in price charged. The measure thus incorporates information about the state of the world before the price change (original price and demand levels) and afterwards (changes in price and demand levels). If demand does not change at all when prices rise or fall, it is said to be perfectly inelastic and the price elasticity measure is equal to zero. This situation describes a good that could be called a necessity the same amount is demanded independent of the price level. Most economic goods are not necessities, however, and the price elasticity will be negative because the price and quantity changes move in opposite directions. The actual magnitude of the elasticity determines whether total revenues (including tax collections) will increase, decrease or remain the same following a price or tax increase. For goods with price elasticities between 0 and 1.0, gross revenues following a price change will rise because the quantity decrease is outweighed by the price increase. For more price elastic goods, the quantity change dominates the price change, and total revenues will fall after a price increase, or rise after a price decrease. Economists also distinguish between short-run and long-run price elasticities. In the long run, consumers have more time and information to respond to price changes by substituting other goods and services for the now more costly one. This means that in the face of a permanent price increase, consumers may reduce their demand somewhat in the immediate future, but they will normally make an even larger adjustment after some time has passed. Price elasticities can vary widely from study to study for a particular alcoholic beverage, and for different types of alcoholic beverages as well. In 1993, for example, Leung and 9

10 Phelps 1 reviewed 15 studies that used data aggregated at the state or national levels. Estimated price elasticities for beer ranged from 0.12 to 1.07 in those studies. Similar ranges were found in estimates of price elasticities for wine and spirits. Leung and Phelps concluded that the best point estimates of price elasticities for use in analyzing these beverages were 0.3 for beer, -1.0 for wine, and 1.5 for spirits. These are the most widely cited estimates in the alcohol abuse literature to this day, and they consequently are the values that are employed in the estimations presented below. There may also be considerable variation in the effective price elasticities for different groups of alcohol consumers. The research in this area is mixed and somewhat inconclusive. But there are strong indications that younger drinkers are more sensitive to price changes than others. This finding is particularly germane for the forging of alcohol policies in State of Texas because of its comparatively youthful population. One of the more recent and extensive studies of price elasticity for younger beer drinkers was completed as a part of the NBER Working Paper Series in Focusing on a U.S. panel of drinkers between the ages of 17 and 27 the age range for which the prevalence of alcohol dependence and abuse is highest, the authors estimated a 0.29 short-run price elasticity of demand, and a long-run price elasticity of more than twice that amount. This discrepancy between short- and long-run elasticities is important because it implies two inter-related things: as time passes following a permanent increase in the excise tax, beverage-specific collections will fall because of even further consumption reductions, but so will the myriad of social costs associated with alcohol use. The authors of this last study also found strong evidence of addictive aspects to beer consumption. This finding is of particular interest to Texas policymakers because of the 1 S. F. Leung and C. E. Phelps, My kingdom for a drink? : A review of estimates of the price sensitivity of demand for alcoholic beverages. In: Hilton, M.E. and Bloss, G., eds., Economics and the Prevention of Alcohol-Related Problems. NIAAA Research Monograph No. 25, NIH Pub. No Michael Grossman, Frank J. Chaloupka, and Ismail Sirtalan, An Empirical Analysis of Alcohol Addiction: Results from the Monitoring the Futures Panels. Working Paper No. 5200, National Bureau of Economic Research, July

11 demographic structure of the state s population, discussed in a later section. Texas Alcohol Taxes There are five specific state taxes applied to the sale and/or consumption of alcohol in Texas, as detailed below. 3 In addition, retail sales of alcohol are subject to the 6.25 percent state sales tax, and to additional, varying levies at the county and city levels. 1. Mixed Beverage Drinks Gross Receipts Tax (Revenue Code 3250): A tax of 14 percent is imposed on the gross receipts of a permittee received from the sale of mixed beverages on the premises of the permittee. The tax has been at this level since 1990, when it replaced the 12 percent levy enacted in It was first established in 1971 at the level of 10 percent. There is no corresponding tax at the federal level. This tax is collected by the Texas Comptroller of Public Accounts (Comptroller). 2. Liquor Tax (Revenue Code 3253): A state wholesale tax on the sale of distilled liquors is imposed at the rate of $2.40 per gallon. The tax has been at this level since 1984, when it replaced the $2.00 levy enacted in The federal levy on liquor is $13.50 per gallon, or almost six times the state assessment. A two percent discount is allowed for timely payment, and the tax is collected by the Texas Alcoholic Beverage Commission (TABC). 3. Beer Tax (Revenue code 3258): A state wholesale tax on the first sale or first importation of beer is imposed at the rate of $6.00 per barrel, based on 31 standard gallons per barrel. The tax has been at this level since 1984, when it replaced the $5.00 levy enacted in The federal tax on beer is three times higher at $18.00 per barrel. A two percent discount is allowed for timely payment, and the tax is collected by the TABC. 4. Wine Tax (Revenue Code 3259): A state wholesale tax is imposed on the sale of wine based on alcohol content. The 11

12 tax is 20.4 cents per gallon for alcohol volume of 14 percent or less, 40.8 cents per gallon for alcohol volume above 14 percent, and 51.6 cents per gallon for sparkling wine. The corresponding federal tax rates are four to six times higher than these levels. A two percent discount is allowed for timely payment, and the tax is collected by the TABC 5. Malt Liquor (Ale) Tax (Revenue code 3265): A state wholesale tax of $0.198 per gallon is imposed on malt liquor containing alcohol in excess of four percent by weight. The tax has been at this level since 1984, when it replaced the $0.165 levy enacted in In this case, the federal rate is about three times higher at $0.58 per gallon. A two percent discount is allowed for timely payment, and the tax is collected by the TABC To put these levies into a more familiar context, consider the different tax rates per serving data presented in Table 1. The beer tax in Texas adds some 1.8 cents to the cost of a single 12- ounce beer. This is about 24 percent below the average for all states. The Texas wine tax adds only about 0.9 cents to a 5- ounce serving, or just under one-third the national figure. At 2.7 cents per 1.5 ounce serving, the Texas liquor tax is about one-third lower than the U.S. state average. Clearly, just in comparison with other states, there would appear to be ample room and reason for increasing Texas alcohol levies. 3 A sixth tax of $0.05 per drink on airline and passenger train beverage sales is not considered here, both because its magnitude is relatively small and it is not readily amenable to modeling within the scope of this study. 12

13 Table 1: Excise Tax per Serving Comparison BEVERAGE CATEGORY TEXAS ALL STATE AVERAGE FEDERAL TEXAS AS PERCENTAGE OF 50- STATE AVERAGE Beer (12 oz.) $0.018 $0.023 $ % Wine (5 oz.) $0.009 $0.029 $ % Liquor (1.5 oz.) $0.027 $0.042 $ % By the time the Texas Legislature next convenes, almost two decades will have passed since most of these state taxes were last increased. In 1985, the first full year following increases in all of these tax rates, combined alcohol taxes accounted for about 3.1 percent of all state tax collections. By 2000 their relative contribution fell by one-third to 2.1 percent, despite an additional increase of two percent in the Mixed Beverage Tax enacted in Over the same period, the purchasing power of a tax dollar declined by 38 percent due to inflation. If the Legislature were to wish to restore the same real tax value established in 1984, these excise taxes should be increased by about 77 percent in the next session. Figure 1 shows how the relative importance of these different taxes has changed over the last two decades. 4 The Mixed Beverage Tax has grown from just over half of all collections in 1981 to almost 70 percent by The share of the Beer Tax was cut by one-third, from 28 to 19 percent, while the relative contribution of the Liquor Tax was halved, from almost 19 percent to just over 9 percent. Together, these three taxes accounted for 97.7 percent of alcoholic beverage consumption taxes in Figure 1: Alcohol Tax Revenues by Type as a Share of Total The declining shares of the beer and liquor taxes are primarily due 70% to the fact that they are calculated on the basis of the physical quantity sold rather than the final price to the purchaser. 60% This means that they are inherently insensitive to inflation following their implementation. In contrast, the Mixed 50% Beverage Tax is calculated as a percentage of the gross receipts 40% 4 30% The Wine and Malt Liquor taxes are excluded from this graph because they collectively represent only about two to three percent of state alcohol consumption tax collections 20% throughout the period. 10% 0%

14 of the vendor, so when sellers raise prices to account for inflation this tax is automatically indexed. In fiscal year 2000, all six of these state alcohol taxes combined averaged just under $25 per resident of the state, or about $2 per month. When it is recognized that many of these levies are collected from out-of-state visitors, the actual tax burden on the typical Texas resident is even lower. Furthermore, because federal levies are several times higher for all categories of alcoholic beverages, the excise taxes imposed by the State of Texas represent a relatively small part of the final price of alcohol to the user. It would thus appear that there is a considerable opportunity to increase these state taxes without unduly burdening Texas consumers. Consumption Trends and Demographic Conditions in Texas The Texas Alcoholic Beverage Commission (TABC) provided data shown below on per capita consumption of different types of alcoholic beverages for fiscal years 1991 through Figure 2: Per Capita Alcohol Consumption FY91 FY92 FY93 FY94 FY95 FY96 FY97 FY98 FY99 FY00 Beer Other 14

15 Consumption of all types of alcohol appear to be steady or rising early in this decade, abruptly decreasing during the middle of the decade, and turning back upwards by the end of the decade. The trends shown here are consistent with national patterns, and somewhat difficult to explain at first glance. The real total price (including excise taxes) of most alcoholic beverages has been declining over the last two decades. The last over haul of federal excise taxes occurred in 1991, and of state excise taxes in Since these taxes are not indexed to inflation, their real value has been declining steadily ever since. According to economic demand theory, this decline in real price should lead to increases in consumption, yet virtually all trend data of this sort show a dip in consumption during the mid- to late-1990s, with some moderate increases thereafter. The principal explanation for this apparent anomaly is the changing demographic profile of the domestic population. Put most simply, tastes and preferences change as people grow older. With the aging of the baby boom generation, more and more individuals are moving into higher age brackets that typically tend to consume less alcohol. By the mid-1990s baby boomers were in the age group, and had largely passed their peak alcoholic consumption years. In addition, some researchers have taken these mid-1990s consumption dips as an indication of the long-run response of consumers to the excise tax increases implemented several years before. By the end of the decade, the decline in real prices began again to take precedence, and consumption rates started to rise. The demographic situation in Texas is much different from that of the U.S., however. As Figure 3 shows, the Texas population is much younger than the nation as a whole. In the year 2000, Texas had a higher proportion of its population in all age groups up until the age of 40, and a lower proportion in all age groups thereafter. Throughout the 1990s, the average age of the Texas population was about 2.3 years less than the U.S. mean, and the gap has been modestly increasing. This demographic difference has several important policy implications for the State of Texas. Figure 3: Age Distribution of the Population 15

16 First, the 33.0% alcoholic beverage of 30.0% 27.0% 24.0% choice for younger persons is beer. Not surprisingl 21.0% y, then, the 18.0% 15.0% distributio n of alcohol Texas United States consumption in Texas differs markedly from the typical United States consumer. On a per capita basis, Texans consume about 25 percent more beer, 26 percent less wine, and 19 percent less distilled spirits than U.S. consumers as a whole. Taking all beverages together, Texans consume about five percent more alcohol per capita than their national counterparts. 5 This is due both to the generally younger population and the depressed level of state excise taxes. Second, the generally younger population in Texas presents a great opportunity for public policymakers. Economic theory provides several explanations for why youths and young adults would be more sensitive to price changes than older age groups. The proportion of disposable income which goes towards alcohol expenditures is likely to be much higher for youths and young adults, mainly because of their lower overall incomes. They are much more responsive to peer pressure and less addicted than adult alcohol consumers, and they tend to discount the future much more heavily. All of these factors combine to suggest a higher price elasticity of demand for younger drinkers, so that perceptible excise tax increases could well deter many of them from becoming alcohol-dependent or abusive, with the attendant large social and private costs. 5 National Institute on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism, Surveillance Report #55: Apparent Per Capita Alcohol Consumption: National, State and Regional Trends, December

17 Fiscal and Economic Effects of Increased Alcohol Taxes This section first looks at the effects of increasing three of the five state taxes described above; the beer tax, the liquor tax, and the gross receipts tax applied to on-premises consumption at licensed commercial establishments. 6 Following that, the estimated reductions in alcohol consumption are used to produce aggregate estimates of reductions in future alcoholrelated costs to society that can reasonably be expected. Figures are forecast for the single year 2004, which is the first full year after the Texas Legislature next convenes. The estimated population for that year is obtained by applying the average growth rate over the last decade to the Census 2000 count for the state. Per capita consumption is estimated using the average of annual figures for the last decade as reported by the TABC, and shown earlier in Figure 2. These estimates further assume that wholesalers pass all taxes along to retailers, and that retailers include these taxes in their markups establishing final prices to consumers. An average retail markup rate of 40 percent is employed here. Price elasticities used for beer and liquor are as reported in the Leung and Phelps study cited earlier. Beer Tax Effects Based on a limited telephone survey of industry representatives, it was determined that the average wholesale cost of beer is presently about $180 per barrel. The estimated wholesale price was then forecast for 2004 using the average annual increase in the Producers Price Index over the past decade, resulting in a figure of $ per barrel, including the existing state excise tax of $6.00 per barrel. Applying the 40 percent retail markup to this figure produced the estimated retail price of $ per barrel in With no change in the excise tax on beer, the retail price in 2004 is estimated to average about $4.89 per six-pack. A doubling of the state excise tax to $12 per barrel would raise this average just 16 cents to $5.05 per six-pack. This would represent a 3.1 percent increase. 17

18 Table 2 presents the projected price, quantity and tax changes estimated for beer excise tax increases of 28, 50 and 100 percent. The 28 percent figure would bring Texas in line with the national average on a per serving basis. Table 2: Short-term Effects of Increases in the Beer Excise Tax in 2004 IN EXCISE TAX TAX RATE PER BARREL RETAIL PRICE PER BARREL PRICE QUANTITY EXCISE TAX SALES TAX No Change $6.00 $ % $7.68 $ % -0.26% $32,057,129 $1,979,835 50% $9.00 $ % -0.47% $57,125,806 $3,525, % $12.00 $ % -0.93% $113,710,396 $7,002,647 ASSUMPTIONS: Population: 22,175,480 Per Capita Consumption: barrels per year Base Quantity: 18,920,377 barrels Wholesale Price: $ per barrel Retail Markup: 40% Price Elasticity: Baseline Beer Excise Tax Collected in 2004: $115,875,260 With a short-run price elasticity for beer demand of just -0.3, a 10 percent price hike would reduce demand by only 3 percent. This means that both excise and sales tax collections would immediately rise with any price increase. While beer retailers would surely resist any additional excise taxes, their opposition would be somewhat muted by the fact that their gross revenue collections would increase by more than $112 million. After deducting the additional excise tax payments, however, their actual margins would decline by a small amount ($1.7 million) equal to about 0.03 percent of baseline revenues. Clearly, the effect of raising the beer excise tax in line with national averages would be a boon to the state s revenue base. Combined increases in the excise and sales taxes would reach more than $60 million, a gain of over 50 percent over the baseline excise tax collection. 6 The wine and malt liquor taxes are not considered here both because of their relatively small scale and the unavailability of suitable data. 18

19 Liquor Tax Effects Using data provided on the Distilled Spirits Council of the United States website, 7 it was determined that the federal excise tax of $13.50 represented about 25 percent of the final retail price of distilled spirits in The estimated retail price was then forecast for 2004 using the average annual increase in the Producers Price Index over the past decade, resulting in a figure of $57.37 per gallon, including the existing state excise tax of $2.40. With no change in the excise tax on liquor, the retail price in 2004 is estimated to average about $15.16 per liter. An increase to bring Texas in line with national averages would increase the state excise tax to $3.74 per gallon would raise this average by 50 cents to $15.66 per liter. This would represent a 3.3 percent increase. Table 3 presents the projected price, and tax changes estimated for distilled spirits excise tax increases of 25, 56 and 100 percent. Once again, the 56 percent figure would bring Texas in line with the national average on a per serving basis. Table 3: Short-term Effects of Increases in the Liquor Excise Tax in 2004 IN EXCISE TAX TAX RATE PER BARREL RETAIL PRICE PER BARREL PRICE QUANTITY EXCISE TAX SALES TAX No Change $2.40 $ % $3.00 $ % -2.20% $12,067,183 ($619,109) 56% $3.74 $ % -4.92% $26,203,604 ($1,459,157) 100% $4.80 $ % -8.78% $44,696,357 ($2,789,020) ASSUMPTIONS: Population: 22,175,480 Per Capita Consumption: gallons per year Base Quantity: 22,134,012 gallons Wholesale Price: $40.98 per gallon Retail Markup: 40% Price Elasticity: Baseline Liquor Excise Tax Collected in 2004: $54,222,691 The sales tax collection drops with any increase in the liquor excise tax a consequence of the high price elasticity of demand for distilled spirits. With an elasticity of 1.5, a 10 percent 7 See 19

20 price increase would lead to a 15 percent decline in demand. Under these circumstances, gross revenues following the price hike necessarily decrease, as must the sales tax collected on those purchases. But the drop in sales tax collections does not approach the magnitude of the increased excise tax collections. As healthy as this may be for the state treasury, any proposed increase in the distilled spirits tax can be expected to be resisted strongly by the industry because the dollar value of retail sales and aftertax margins will fall. Gross Receipts Tax Effects The analysis here is somewhat more speculative because of the nature of the data that are available. While the total dollar sales subject to this tax can be easily calculated, no data exist on the average retail price or volume of consumption subject to this tax. Similarly, there has been no research specifically dedicated to the price elasticity of demand for on-premises consumption of alcoholic beverages. Accordingly, we make two significant simplifying assumptions. First, it is assumed that consumers are somewhat less sensitive to the price of these beverages than they are to purchases of alcoholic beverages for off-site consumption. For one thing, many of these purchases are made in combination with the purchase of meals at commercial establishments. Accordingly, they represent only a fraction of the total bill the consumer will be paying, and any increase in the gross receipts tax would be diluted by the other (principally food) items on the final bill. In addition, many of these sales are to business customers who are less concerned with price because they can generally expense these purchases. Accordingly, for the purposes of this analysis, a price elasticity of 0.20 is assumed. Second, it is assumed that the average price of an alcoholic beverage subject to this tax is $5.00 in the year This figure is undoubtedly low, but it will serve to reduce the magnitude of the projected fiscal impacts of any increase. Finally, it is assumed that retailers incorporate the anticipated gross receipts tax directly into their pricing structures. What 20

21 this means in practice is that to recover their other costs and target profit, they must inflate the price to the consumer by something more than the level of the gross receipts tax. At the present 14 percent tax level, their prices would have to be increased by percent to accomplish this. If the tax rate were to increase to 15 percent, they would have to tack on another percent to break even. Table 4: Short-term Effects of Increases in the Gross Receipts Tax in 2004 IN EXCISE TAX TAX RATE PER BARREL RETAIL PRICE PER BARREL PRICE QUANTITY EXCISE TAX SALES TAX No Change 14% $ % Increase 15% $ % -0.24% $32,735,578 $1,683,050 2% Increase 16% $ % -0.48% $66,085,983 $3,395,886 ASSUMPTIONS: Price Elasticity: Baseline Liquor Excise Tax Collected in 2004: $401,747,594 Table 4 presents forecasts of price, quantity and tax changes if the Mixed Beverage Gross Receipts tax is increased to 15 and 16 percent. Roughly speaking, each one percent increment in this tax would add an additional $34 to $35 million to state tax collections. At the same time, each one percent increase would decrease demand for mixed beverages by about one-fourth of a percentage point. Costs to the State of Texas Associated with Alcohol Abuse Alcohol abuse traditionally has been considered primarily a social problem. However, the economic implications are equally substantial. In a study for the National Institute on Drug Abuse (NIDA), it was estimated that the combined economic costs alone of alcohol and drug abuse in 1995 exceeded $276 billion for the United States as a whole. Adjusting for price and population increases since then, the current estimated economic cost of substance abuse in America is in the vicinity of $340 billion per year. This amounted to almost 4 percent of the gross domestic product (GDP), or about $1,200 per person nationwide. Significant as they are, these statistics reflect only measurable economic costs - just a portion of the total costs of substance abuse to society. Primarily because of methodological 21

22 limitations, quantitative analyses of the impact of substance abuse do not account adequately for a potentially significant volume of non-economic costs simply because they are either difficult or impossible to measure accurately. For example, the human and social costs of fractured family and community relationships with substance-abusers are substantial, but such costs are generally excluded from these analyses. Categories of Costs Three principal categories of costs of substance abuse are considered in the literature: (1) expenditures incurred in attempting to prevent substance abuse or treating its health consequences, (2) productivity effects resulting from premature death, elevated morbidity rates, or the secondary consequences of criminal activity, and (3) other societal effects. From an economist s perspective, many if not most of the benefits of substance abuse programs are actually avoided costs - costs that would have been incurred had the program not been in place and effective. Treatment Costs This is the most immediate and easily identified type of cost attributable to alcohol and drug abuse. This category also encompasses the costs associated with treating the medical consequences of alcohol abuse that are incurred by public and private agencies other than drug and alcohol treatment programs hospitals, in particular. These medical consequences add up to about twice the amount expended annually on drug and alcohol treatment programs. Productivity Losses By a large margin, the most significant economic costs of substance abuse are reflected in reduced production and productive activity in the economy. The increased mortality, morbidity and crime rates stemming from alcohol abuse take actual and potentially productive workers away from their jobs or out of the legitimate labor force entirely, both temporarily and permanently. 22

23 Other Social Costs Significant property losses and incremental criminal justice system expenditures can also be related to substance abuse. Vehicle crashes and fires cost substantial amounts of money to individuals, insurers and government. The costs of police protection, adjudication, and incarceration of individuals for crimes that are derivative of substance abuse are similarly impressive. Cost Levels in Texas TCADA has estimated the costs associated with substance abuse during 1997 at $19.3 billion, with alcohol abuse representing $11.1 billion of that total, or $ per capita. After allowing for population increases and inflation, this figure is projected to rise to $14.9 billion by 2004, equivalent to $ per Texan. 8 Table 5 provides more detail. Table 5: Texas Costs Associated with Alcohol Abuse CATEGORY Core Costs (in billions) $9.28 $12.45 Treatment $0.47 $0.63 Morbidity (lost productivity) $6.12 $8.21 Mortality (premature death) $2.69 $3.61 Other Related Direct Costs $1.83 $2.45 TOTAL $11.10 $14.90 Source: TCADA for 1997; for 2004 estimates Distribution of Costs Four major groups bear the costs of alcohol abuse: (1) abusers and their immediate family and friends, (2) government, (3) private insurers, and (4) crime and accident victims. Taken together, these latter three groups can be considered the nonabusing segment of society, although this is somewhat of an oversimplification. The non-abusing sector collectively pays about 55 cents of every dollar in direct substance abuse costs, and its share increases somewhat because of indirect transfers. Costs primarily absorbed by abusers cover lost legitimate earnings and household productivity due to impaired or curtailed 8 For purposes of this analysis, annual inflation is assumed to be 2.5 percent. 23

24 functioning in the labor market, incarceration, and the pursuit of criminal rather than legitimate economic careers. These costs account for the balance of the total, but they are shifted somewhat to different groups. For example, reduced legitimate earnings results in a loss for government through reduced tax revenues, which then translates into increased taxes or reduced services for the remainder of society. Incremental government services that can be traced to substance abuse include many of the costs of substance abuse programs themselves, supplemental criminal justice and highway safety expenditures, and various social insurance mechanisms. Obviously, these costs are passed along to abusing and non-abusing taxpayers alike, with the abusing population paying even less than their per-capita share because of reduced earnings. Impact on the State Of Texas It is estimated that approximately 39 percent of the total cost of abuse is borne by state government, both in terms of direct treatment expenditures and indirect fiscal effects associated with increased crime, lost productivity, etc. 9 Applying this figure to the data on total costs presented in Table 5 suggests that, if present trends continue, the State of Texas will bear the burden of $5.81 billion in alcohol-related abuse in 2004, the equivalent of $216 per person. 10 However, if demand for alcohol were to be reduced one percent, the corresponding reduction in abuse would have a positive fiscal impact on the State of approximately $58.1 million. Results and Conclusions Amid rising concern over Texas fiscal status, policymakers are paying close attention to opportunities to both increase revenue 9 Harwood, H.; Fountain, D.; and Livermore, G. (1998). The Economic Costs of Alcohol and Drug Abuse in the United States, Report to the National Institute on Drug Abuse and the National Institute on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism. NIH Publication No This estimate is consistent with other findings. For example, a recent study by the National Center on Addiction and Substance Abuse (CASA) at Columbia University estimated that, on average, state governments across the U.S. spent $277 per person dealing with the impact of substance abuse in 1998, a figure that would grow with inflation to $321 in 2004 ( Shoveling Up: The Impact of Substance Abuse on State Budgets. January Assuming that alcohol abuse represents between 50 percent and two-thirds of the total cost of substance abuse, the findings from TCADA are reinforced by the data from CASA. 24

25 and reduce costs. Raising alcohol taxes would appear to accomplish both. Since demand for alcohol appears to be relatively inelastic (i.e., not very price-sensitive), raising the effective price (which is the net effect of a tax increase) will yield only a modest reduction in consumption in the near term, meaning that a significant amount of additional tax revenue will generated. Table 6 provides an illustration, and is based on the assumption that beer and liquor taxes are brought in line with national averages while the gross receipts tax on mixed drinks is raised one percentage point. The results are enlightening; this seemingly marginal change in tax rates would net the State approximately $93 million in additional tax revenue in Table 6: The Fiscal Impact of Increased Alcohol Taxes CATEGORY EXCISE TAX IMPACT SALES TAX IMAPCT PRICE QUANTITY POSITIVE FISCAL IMPACT DUE TO REDUCTION IN ABUSE Raising the Beer Tax 28% $32.1 million $2.0 million 0.87% -0.26% $43.0 million Raising the Liquor Tax 56% $26.2 million ($1.5 million) 3.28% -4.92% $12.6 million Raising the Mixed Drink Tax One Percentage Point $32.7 million $1.7 million 1.18% -0.24% $2.5 million TOTALS $91.0 million $2.2 million 1.41% -1.28% $58.1 million Even the modest reductions in demand observed under this scenario yield an additional positive impact to the state budget in the form of reduced expenditures related to alcohol abuse. As has been well-documented, alcohol and substance abuse costs the Texas economy and state treasury billions of dollars annually; even the small drop in demand expected under this scenario would have a positive fiscal impact to the State of an additional $58.1 million, putting the initial total annual fiscal impact in excess of $152 million. As a result, increasing alcohol taxes is one of the clearest win-win options presently available to policymakers, since, depending on consumer price-sensitivity, it either generates substantial tax revenue or causes a significant reduction in abuse-related costs. In either case, Texas is better off than under the current system. 25

SLIDE 5: Graph of Trends in Federal Alcoholic Beverage Taxes

SLIDE 5: Graph of Trends in Federal Alcoholic Beverage Taxes REMARKS By Frank J. Chaloupka, PhD Associate Professor, University of Illinois at Chicago Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research Alcohol Policy XI Plenary Session III SLIDE 1: Economic

More information

Economics and Alcohol Taxation

Economics and Alcohol Taxation Economics and Alcohol Taxation Frank J. Chaloupka ImpacTeen Project, University of Illinois at Chicago and the National Bureau of Economic Research and Michael Grossman, Henry Saffer, Henry Wechsler, Adit

More information

The Effects of Excise Tax on Beer Consumption

The Effects of Excise Tax on Beer Consumption The Effects of Excise Tax on Beer Consumption By: Matt Zuzic Economics 226 University of Akron October 16, 2007 Abstract: My paper discusses the effect of an excise tax on the consumption of beer. My thesis

More information

Economic Perspectives on Alcohol Taxation. and

Economic Perspectives on Alcohol Taxation. and Economic Perspectives on Alcohol Taxation Frank J. Chaloupka University of Illinois at Chicago and National Bureau of Economic Research and Michael Grossman, CUNY and NBER Henry Saffer, Kean College and

More information

The Economics of Alcohol and Cancer/Chronic Disease

The Economics of Alcohol and Cancer/Chronic Disease The Economics of Alcohol and Cancer/Chronic Disease Frank J. Chaloupka, University of Illinois at Chicago World Cancer Congress Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia, 2 October 2018 Overview Economic Costs of Excessive

More information

DOLLARS AND SENSE: THE COST OF SUBSTANCE ABUSE TO MISSOURI SCOPE OF THE PROBLEM Alcohol and other drug abuse is ranked the most costly health care issue in the United States. Substance abuse and addiction

More information

THE EFFECTS OF ALCOHOL EXCISE TAX INCREASES ON PUBLIC HEALTH AND SAFETY IN TEXAS

THE EFFECTS OF ALCOHOL EXCISE TAX INCREASES ON PUBLIC HEALTH AND SAFETY IN TEXAS THE EFFECTS OF ALCOHOL EXCISE TAX INCREASES ON PUBLIC HEALTH AND SAFETY IN TEXAS Megan C. Diaz, MA Frank J. Chaloupka, PhD David H. Jernigan, PhD Report prepared for March 2, 2015 Updated March 29, 2016

More information

POLICY BRIEF. Government-Run Liquor Stores The Social Impact of Privatization JOHN PULITO & ANTONY DAVIES, PHD EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

POLICY BRIEF. Government-Run Liquor Stores The Social Impact of Privatization JOHN PULITO & ANTONY DAVIES, PHD EXECUTIVE SUMMARY POLICY BRIEF from the COMMONWEALTH FOUNDATION Vol. 21, No. 03 October 2009 Government-Run Liquor Stores The Social Impact of Privatization JOHN PULITO & ANTONY DAVIES, PHD EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Privatization

More information

Initial Report of Oregon s State Epidemiological Outcomes Workgroup. Prepared by:

Initial Report of Oregon s State Epidemiological Outcomes Workgroup. Prepared by: Alcohol Consumption and Consequences in Oregon Prepared by: Addictions & Mental Health Division 5 Summer Street NE Salem, OR 9731-1118 To the reader, This report is one of three epidemiological profiles

More information

THE DRINKS MARKET PERFORMANCE. Prepared for the Drinks Industry Group of Ireland By Anthony Foley Dublin City University Business School

THE DRINKS MARKET PERFORMANCE. Prepared for the Drinks Industry Group of Ireland By Anthony Foley Dublin City University Business School THE DRINKS MARKET PERFORMANCE 2017 Prepared for the Drinks Industry Group of Ireland By Anthony Foley Dublin City University Business School Foreword by DIGI The Drinks Industry Group of Ireland (DIGI)

More information

The Idaho Model of Distilled Spirits Distribution. Citizen Owned for the Benefit of All

The Idaho Model of Distilled Spirits Distribution. Citizen Owned for the Benefit of All The Idaho Model of Distilled Spirits Distribution Citizen Owned for the Benefit of All 1 Historical Perspective The WHY The 18th Amendment established Prohibition in the U.S. in 1920. In 1933, the 21 st

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ALCOHOL CONSUMPTION AND TAX DIFFERENTIALS BETWEEN BEER, WINE AND SPIRITS. Working Paper No. 3200

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ALCOHOL CONSUMPTION AND TAX DIFFERENTIALS BETWEEN BEER, WINE AND SPIRITS. Working Paper No. 3200 NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ALCOHOL CONSUMPTION AND TAX DIFFERENTIALS BETWEEN BEER, WINE AND SPIRITS Henry Saffer Working Paper No. 3200 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

FY 2004 STATE BUDGET ADDICTION PREVENTION AND TREATMENT SUMMARY ANTICIPATED RESOURCES FOR THE FISCAL YEAR GENERAL FUND

FY 2004 STATE BUDGET ADDICTION PREVENTION AND TREATMENT SUMMARY ANTICIPATED RESOURCES FOR THE FISCAL YEAR GENERAL FUND No.12 2003 1675 Whitehorse-Mercerville Road, Hamilton, NJ 08619 Tel.: 609/689-0121 l FAX 609/689-3244 POLICY REPORT FY 2004 STATE BUDGET ADDICTION PREVENTION AND TREATMENT SUMMARY Governor James McGreevey

More information

Substance Misuse in New Hampshire: An Update on Costs to the State s Economy and Initial Impacts of Public Policies to Reduce Them

Substance Misuse in New Hampshire: An Update on Costs to the State s Economy and Initial Impacts of Public Policies to Reduce Them Substance Misuse in New Hampshire: An Update on Costs to the State s Economy and Initial Impacts of Public Policies to Reduce Them May 2017 Prepared by: Sponsored by: Table of Contents EXECUTIVE SUMMARY...

More information

How Price Increases Reduce Tobacco Use

How Price Increases Reduce Tobacco Use How Price Increases Reduce Tobacco Use Frank J. Chaloupka Director, ImpacTeen, University of Illinois at Chicago www.uic.edu/~fjc www.impacteen.org www.tobaccoevidence.net TUPTI, Kansas City, July 8 2002

More information

Tobacco and Cigarette Taxes

Tobacco and Cigarette Taxes Idaho Center for Fiscal Policy Primer Tobacco and Cigarette Taxes Idaho s Tobacco and Cigarette Taxes Generate Revenue Used to Help Communities Thrive In order for Idaho communities to thrive, they need

More information

THE PERRYMAN GROUP. 510 N. Valley Mills Dr., Suite 300. Waco, TX ph , fax

THE PERRYMAN GROUP. 510 N. Valley Mills Dr., Suite 300. Waco, TX ph , fax November 2014 An Economic Assessment of the Cost of Cancer in Texas and the Benefits of the Cancer Prevention and Research Institute of Texas (CPRIT) and its Programs: 2014 Update THE PERRYMAN GROUP 510

More information

MISSION STATEMENT OBJECTIVE

MISSION STATEMENT OBJECTIVE Work Plan July 1, 2013 June 30, 2014 MISSION STATEMENT The DUI Task Force of Richland County represents a diverse cross-section of the community including citizens, government officials, law enforcement,

More information

MARIJUANA LEGALIZATION. INITIATIVE STATUTE.

MARIJUANA LEGALIZATION. INITIATIVE STATUTE. PROPOSITION MARIJUANA LEGALIZATION. OFFICIAL TITLE AND SUMMARY Legalizes marijuana under state law, for use by adults 21 or older. Designates state agencies to license and regulate marijuana industry.

More information

Hana Ross, PhD American Cancer Society and the International Tobacco Evidence Network (ITEN)

Hana Ross, PhD American Cancer Society and the International Tobacco Evidence Network (ITEN) The Costs of Smoking Hana Ross, PhD American Cancer Society and the International Tobacco Evidence Network (ITEN) Why Do We Study the Cost of Smoking? To assess the economic impact of smoking behavior

More information

Module 6: Substance Use

Module 6: Substance Use Module 6: Substance Use Part 1: Overview of Substance Abuse I am Martha Romney and I am presenting on substance abuse. This module focuses on the healthy people 2020 objective to reduce substance abuse

More information

Alcohol Indicators Report Executive Summary

Alcohol Indicators Report Executive Summary Alcohol Indicators Report Executive Summary A framework of alcohol indicators describing the consumption of use, patterns of use, and alcohol-related harms in Nova Scotia NOVEMBER 2005 Foreword Alcohol

More information

Cigarette Consumption: Estimating the Effects of an Excise Cigarette Tax in California

Cigarette Consumption: Estimating the Effects of an Excise Cigarette Tax in California Caroline Hymel PPPA6017 Cigarette Consumption: Estimating the Effects of an Excise Cigarette Tax in California Summary Recently, California passed Proposition 56, which increased the tax on cigarettes

More information

Tobacco & Poverty. Tobacco Use Makes the Poor Poorer; Tobacco Tax Increases Can Change That. Introduction. Impacts of Tobacco Use on the Poor

Tobacco & Poverty. Tobacco Use Makes the Poor Poorer; Tobacco Tax Increases Can Change That. Introduction. Impacts of Tobacco Use on the Poor Policy Brief February 2018 Tobacco & Poverty Tobacco Use Makes the Poor Poorer; Tobacco Tax Increases Can Change That Introduction Tobacco use is the world s leading cause of preventable diseases and premature

More information

THE ECONOMICS OF TOBACCO AND TOBACCO TAXATION IN BANGLADESH

THE ECONOMICS OF TOBACCO AND TOBACCO TAXATION IN BANGLADESH THE ECONOMICS OF TOBACCO AND TOBACCO TAXATION IN BANGLADESH Abul Barkat, PhD Professor of Economics, University of Dhaka & Chief Advisor (Hon.), HDRC Email: info@hdrc-bd.com Advocacy for Tobacco Taxation

More information

Why the Increase In Obesity

Why the Increase In Obesity Obesity From an Economist s Perspective Eric Finkelstein, PhD, MHA RTI INTERNATIONAL The Economics of Obesity (outline) Why the Increase in Obesity Rates Adverse Health Consequences Why do (or should)

More information

Price-based measures to reduce alcohol consumption

Price-based measures to reduce alcohol consumption Price-based measures to reduce alcohol consumption Andrew Leicester (with Rachel Griffith and Martin O Connell) Health Economics Research Unit, University of Aberdeen 12 th March 2013 Introduction Governments

More information

I N C R E A S I N G C I G A R E T T E E X C I S E T A X I S BAD POLICY FOR OREGON

I N C R E A S I N G C I G A R E T T E E X C I S E T A X I S BAD POLICY FOR OREGON 7 I N C R E A S I N G C I G A R E T T E E X C I S E T A X I S BAD POLICY FOR OREGON THE TOP REASONS WHY A HIGHER CIGARETTE TAX IS BAD FOR OREGON ONE TWO THREE FOUR INCREASING THE STATE CIGARETTE TAX WILL

More information

Alcohol Policy and Social Change: Creating Safer Community Environments

Alcohol Policy and Social Change: Creating Safer Community Environments Alcohol Policy and Social Change: Creating Safer Community Environments James F. Mosher, JD Alcohol Policy Consultations March 6, 2012 Presentation at the 7 th Annual Summit on Substance Abuse, Mental

More information

Amendment 72 Increase Cigarette and Tobacco Taxes

Amendment 72 Increase Cigarette and Tobacco Taxes Amendment 72 Increase Cigarette and Tobacco Taxes ANALYSIS Amendment 72 proposes amending the Colorado Constitution to: increase the state tax on a pack of cigarettes from $0.84 to $2.59; increase the

More information

Table 1. Summary of the types of alcohol taxes applied by category of alcohol product. 12

Table 1. Summary of the types of alcohol taxes applied by category of alcohol product. 12 Alcohol Policy Coalition Position Statement July 2009 ALCOHOL PRICING AND TAXATION The issues Link between price, consumption and harm There is a strong link between alcohol price, consumption and resulting

More information

Impact of excise tax on price, consumption and revenue

Impact of excise tax on price, consumption and revenue Impact of excise tax on price, consumption and revenue Introduction Increase in tobacco tax that leads to price increase is expected to reduce tobacco consumption and improve public health. This section

More information

Employee Handbook of the Royal College of Physicians of Ireland. RCPI Policy Group on Alcohol Pre Budget Submission

Employee Handbook of the Royal College of Physicians of Ireland. RCPI Policy Group on Alcohol Pre Budget Submission Employee Handbook of the Royal College of Physicians of Ireland RCPI Policy Group on Alcohol 2014 Pre Budget Submission September 2013 Contents 1. Introduction... 3 2. Recommendations... 5 3. Effect of

More information

5 $3 billion per disease

5 $3 billion per disease $3 billion per disease Chapter at a glance Our aim is to set a market size large enough to attract serious commercial investment from several pharmaceutical companies that see technological opportunites,

More information

TOBACCO TAXATION, TOBACCO CONTROL POLICY, AND TOBACCO USE

TOBACCO TAXATION, TOBACCO CONTROL POLICY, AND TOBACCO USE TOBACCO TAXATION, TOBACCO CONTROL POLICY, AND TOBACCO USE Frank J. Chaloupka Director, ImpacTeen, University of Illinois at Chicago www.uic.edu/~fjc www.impacteen.org The Fact is, Raising Tobacco Prices

More information

A Simple Demand Supply Model of Alcohol Consumption in India Kanupriya Suthar Independent Researcher, India

A Simple Demand Supply Model of Alcohol Consumption in India Kanupriya Suthar Independent Researcher, India A Simple Demand Supply Model of Alcohol Consumption in India Kanupriya Suthar Independent Researcher, India Abstract Alcohol consumption has seen sharp rise in India in last some time. In addition to the

More information

The Meaning of the November Ballot Initiative to Legalize Recreational Marijuana

The Meaning of the November Ballot Initiative to Legalize Recreational Marijuana The Meaning of the November Ballot Initiative to Legalize Recreational Marijuana On Tuesday, November 6, 2018, Michigan citizens will be asked whether they want to legalize recreational marijuana. Medical

More information

Healthy People, Healthy Communities

Healthy People, Healthy Communities Healthy People, Healthy Communities Public Health Policy Statements on Public Health Issues The provincial government plays an important role in shaping policies that impact both individual and community

More information

December 2012 Prepared by:

December 2012 Prepared by: The High Cost of Excessive Alcohol Consumption in New Hampshire December 2012 Prepared by: Table of Contents EXECUTIVE SUMMARY... 3 I. INTRODUCTION... 7 II. PRODUCTIVITY COSTS... 8 A. REDUCED LABOR FORCE

More information

The Effects of Alcohol Excise Tax Increases on. Public Health in Maryland

The Effects of Alcohol Excise Tax Increases on. Public Health in Maryland The Effects of Alcohol Excise Tax Increases on Public Health in Maryland David H. Jernigan PhD Hugh Waters PhD Johns Hopkins Bloomberg School of Public Health December 1, 2009 Acknowledgment: Support for

More information

Attracting Funding for Cancer Prevention Using Economic and Fiscal Tools

Attracting Funding for Cancer Prevention Using Economic and Fiscal Tools Attracting Funding for Cancer Prevention Using Economic and Fiscal Tools Frank J. Chaloupka, University of Illinois at Chicago World Cancer Congress Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia, 3 October 2018 "Sugar, rum,

More information

OUTLOOK FOR U.S. TOBACCO. Tom Capehart Agricultural Economist Economic Research Service U.S. Department of Agriculture

OUTLOOK FOR U.S. TOBACCO. Tom Capehart Agricultural Economist Economic Research Service U.S. Department of Agriculture Outlook 98 For Release: Tuesday February 24, 1998 OUTLOOK FOR U.S. TOBACCO Tom Capehart Agricultural Economist Economic Research Service U.S. Department of Agriculture The outlook for U.S.-grown tobacco

More information

FEDERAL DRUG CONTROL PROGRAMS

FEDERAL DRUG CONTROL PROGRAMS FEDERAL DRUG CONTROL PROGRAMS The President s Proposal: Focuses on preventing drug use before it starts, through education and community action; Increases support for treatment and prevention programs;

More information

Potential Health Effects of Expanding Liquor Licenses to Grocery and Convenience Stores

Potential Health Effects of Expanding Liquor Licenses to Grocery and Convenience Stores KHI.ORG Informing Policy. Improving Health. Potential Health Effects of Expanding Liquor Licenses to Grocery and Convenience Stores Kansas Health Impact Assessment Project MAY 2014 Informing Policy. Improving

More information

CDC and Bridging the Gap: Introducing New State Appropriation, Grants, and Expenditure Data in the STATE System

CDC and Bridging the Gap: Introducing New State Appropriation, Grants, and Expenditure Data in the STATE System CDC and Bridging the Gap: Introducing New State Appropriation, Grants, and Expenditure Data in the STATE System Frank Chaloupka, PhD (University of Illinois-Chicago) Jidong Huang, PhD (University of Illinois-Chicago)

More information

Cannabis use carries significant health risks, especially for people who use it frequently and or/begin to use it at an early age.

Cannabis use carries significant health risks, especially for people who use it frequently and or/begin to use it at an early age. Background: The Centre for Addiction and Mental Health (CAMH) released recommendations for the Legalization of Marijuana (with restrictions and regulations) on October 8, 2014. Addiction Services of Thames

More information

ECONOMICS Component 2 Exploring Economic Issues

ECONOMICS Component 2 Exploring Economic Issues GCE AS Level NEW AS B520U20-1 S16-B520U20-1 ECONOMICS Component 2 Exploring Economic Issues A.M. MONDAY, 23 May 2016 2 hours B520U201 01 ADDITIONAL MATERIALS In addition to this examination paper, you

More information

The Economic Costs of Alcohol Abuse in Alaska, 2016 Update

The Economic Costs of Alcohol Abuse in Alaska, 2016 Update The Economic Costs of Alcohol Abuse in Alaska, 2016 Update Prepared for: Alaska Mental Health Trust Authority March 2017 The Economic Costs of Alcohol Abuse in Alaska, 2016 Update Prepared for: Alaska

More information

Tobacco use is Wisconsin s

Tobacco use is Wisconsin s Focus on... Smoking Increasing tobacco taxes: An evidencebased measure to reduce tobacco use Marion Ceraso, MHS; David Ahrens, MS; Patrick Remington, MD Tobacco use is Wisconsin s single most important

More information

State Report. Pennsylvania

State Report. Pennsylvania State Report Pennsylvania This state report is excerpted from: The 2013 Report to Congress on the Prevention and Reduction of Underage Drinking submitted to Congress by The U.S. Department of Health and

More information

MPA BURNING ISSUES CONFERENCE. Thursday, November 10, 2016

MPA BURNING ISSUES CONFERENCE. Thursday, November 10, 2016 MPA BURNING ISSUES CONFERENCE Thursday, November 10, 2016 Excessive Alcohol Consumpsion Is Expensive Excessive drinking cost Michigan $8.2 billion in 2006 Michigan government paid $3.5 billion (43% of

More information

Pamela S. Erickson, President Public Action Management, PLC April 28-29, 2010

Pamela S. Erickson, President Public Action Management, PLC April 28-29, 2010 Pamela S. Erickson, President Public Action Management, PLC April 28-29, 2010 Why do we need special regulations for businesses that sell alcohol? Why can t alcohol be sold in a free market like other

More information

CONTROL, REGULATION, AND TAXATION OF MARIJUANA AND INDUSTRIAL HEMP ACT PRESENTATION TO LEGISLATIVE TASK FORCE ON OLCC 11/19/14

CONTROL, REGULATION, AND TAXATION OF MARIJUANA AND INDUSTRIAL HEMP ACT PRESENTATION TO LEGISLATIVE TASK FORCE ON OLCC 11/19/14 CONTROL, REGULATION, AND TAXATION OF MARIJUANA AND INDUSTRIAL HEMP ACT PRESENTATION TO LEGISLATIVE TASK FORCE ON OLCC 11/19/14 1 THE BASICS Measure 91 was approved by the voters on Nov. 4. The act is modeled

More information

Assess the view that a minimum price on alcohol is likely to be an effective and equitable intervention to curb externalities from drinking (25)

Assess the view that a minimum price on alcohol is likely to be an effective and equitable intervention to curb externalities from drinking (25) Assess the view that a minimum price on alcohol is likely to be an effective and equitable intervention to curb externalities from drinking (25) Introduction A minimum price of 50 pence per unit has been

More information

STATE OF NEW JERSEY. SENATE, No th LEGISLATURE. Sponsored by: Senator JOSEPH F. VITALE District 19 (Middlesex)

STATE OF NEW JERSEY. SENATE, No th LEGISLATURE. Sponsored by: Senator JOSEPH F. VITALE District 19 (Middlesex) SENATE, No. STATE OF NEW JERSEY th LEGISLATURE INTRODUCED JANUARY, 0 Sponsored by: Senator JOSEPH F. VITALE District (Middlesex) SYNOPSIS Creates new taxable category of alcoholic beverages called flavored

More information

GERMANY. Recorded adult (15+) alcohol consumption by type of alcoholic beverage (in % of pure alcohol), Spirits 20%

GERMANY. Recorded adult (15+) alcohol consumption by type of alcoholic beverage (in % of pure alcohol), Spirits 20% GERMANY SOCIOECOMIC CONTEXT Total population 82,641,000 Annual population growth rate 0.1% Population 15+ years 86% Adult literacy rate - - Population in urban areas 75% Income group (World bank) High

More information

THE ECONOMICS OF TOBACCO AND TOBACCO CONTROL, A DEVELOPMENT ISSUE. ANNETTE DIXON, WORLD BANK DIRECTOR, HUMAN DEVELOPMENT SECTOR

THE ECONOMICS OF TOBACCO AND TOBACCO CONTROL, A DEVELOPMENT ISSUE. ANNETTE DIXON, WORLD BANK DIRECTOR, HUMAN DEVELOPMENT SECTOR THE ECONOMICS OF TOBACCO AND TOBACCO CONTROL, A DEVELOPMENT ISSUE. ANNETTE DIXON, WORLD BANK DIRECTOR, HUMAN DEVELOPMENT SECTOR EUROPE AND CENTRAL ASIA REGION The facts and figures clearly show the enormous

More information

7. Provide information - media campaigns such as know your units, labelling on drinks

7. Provide information - media campaigns such as know your units, labelling on drinks Teacher Notes Introduction This activity encourages students to decide on what measures they believe are appropriate for the regulation of alcohol consumption and to present these views as an argument.

More information

BRIEFING: ARGUMENTS AGAINST MINIMUM PRICING FOR ALCOHOL

BRIEFING: ARGUMENTS AGAINST MINIMUM PRICING FOR ALCOHOL BRIEFING: ARGUMENTS AGAINST MINIMUM PRICING FOR ALCOHOL Scottish Health Action on Alcohol Problems (SHAAP) was established by the Scottish Medical Royal Colleges and Faculties to raise awareness about

More information

AUSTRALIAN CHRONIC DISEASE PREVENTION ALLIANCE. Submission to Senate Standing Committee on Community Affairs

AUSTRALIAN CHRONIC DISEASE PREVENTION ALLIANCE. Submission to Senate Standing Committee on Community Affairs AUSTRALIAN CHRONIC DISEASE PREVENTION ALLIANCE Submission to Senate Standing Committee on Community Affairs Excise Tariff Amendment (2009 Measures No1) Bill 2009 Customs Tariff Amendment (2009 Measures

More information

Executive Summary. Overall conclusions of this report include:

Executive Summary. Overall conclusions of this report include: Executive Summary On November 23, 1998, 46 states settled their lawsuits against the nation s major tobacco companies to recover tobacco-related health care costs, joining four states Mississippi, Texas,

More information

Tobacco Control Program Funding in Indiana: A Critical Assessment. Final Report to the Richard M. Fairbanks Foundation

Tobacco Control Program Funding in Indiana: A Critical Assessment. Final Report to the Richard M. Fairbanks Foundation Tobacco Control Program Funding in Indiana: A Critical Assessment Final Report to the Richard M. Fairbanks Foundation John A. Tauras, PhD Associate Professor, Department of Economics, UIC Faculty Scholar,

More information

San Francisco Alcohol Mitigation Fee Michele Simon, JD, MPH Research and Policy Director Marin Institute

San Francisco Alcohol Mitigation Fee Michele Simon, JD, MPH Research and Policy Director Marin Institute San Francisco Alcohol Mitigation Fee Michele Simon, JD, MPH Research and Policy Director Marin Institute Small Business Commission Meeting July 12, 2010 Who is Marin Institute? National leader in alcohol

More information

Non-Technical Summary of: The War on Illegal Drug Production and Trafficking: An Economic Evaluation of Plan Colombia 1

Non-Technical Summary of: The War on Illegal Drug Production and Trafficking: An Economic Evaluation of Plan Colombia 1 Non-Technical Summary of: The War on Illegal Drug Production and Trafficking: An Economic Evaluation of Plan Colombia 1 by: Daniel Mejía and Pascual Restrepo Fedesarrollo and Universidad de los Andes Original

More information

A Snapshot: Medical Marijuana in Rural New Mexico & Benefits of Legalizing Adult Use of Marijuana in Rural New Mexico

A Snapshot: Medical Marijuana in Rural New Mexico & Benefits of Legalizing Adult Use of Marijuana in Rural New Mexico A Snapshot: Medical Marijuana in Rural New Mexico & Benefits of Legalizing Adult Use of Marijuana in Rural New Mexico A presentation to: NM Legislative Economic & Rural Development Committee November 6,

More information

ATTITUDES AND BEHAVIOURS

ATTITUDES AND BEHAVIOURS ATTITUDES AND BEHAVIOURS About the Foundation for Alcohol Research and Education The Foundation for Alcohol Research and Education (FARE) is an independent, not-for-profit organisation working to stop

More information

The Economics of Tobacco and Tobacco Taxation in Bangladesh: Abul Barkat et.al

The Economics of Tobacco and Tobacco Taxation in Bangladesh: Abul Barkat et.al EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 01. Increase price of cigarette and Bidi by 33% (include this in the upcoming FY 2008-09 National Budget). This will decrease use rate by 14% and 9% in short and long-run respectively;

More information

Reducing Tobacco Use and Secondhand Smoke Exposure: Interventions to Increase the Unit Price for Tobacco Products

Reducing Tobacco Use and Secondhand Smoke Exposure: Interventions to Increase the Unit Price for Tobacco Products Reducing Tobacco Use and Secondhand Smoke Exposure: Interventions to Increase the Unit Price for Tobacco Products Task Force Finding and Rationale Statement Table of Contents Intervention Definition...

More information

New Jersey s Comprehensive Tobacco Control Program: Importance of Sustained Funding

New Jersey s Comprehensive Tobacco Control Program: Importance of Sustained Funding New Jersey s Comprehensive Tobacco Control Program: Importance of Sustained Funding History of Tobacco Control Funding Tobacco use is the leading preventable cause of death in the U.S., killing more than

More information

Mecklenburg County. Alcoholic Beverage Control Board. Annual Report Fiscal Year 2014

Mecklenburg County. Alcoholic Beverage Control Board. Annual Report Fiscal Year 2014 Mecklenburg County Alcoholic Beverage Control Board Annual Report Fiscal Year 2014 3333 North Tryon Street Charlotte, North Carolina 28206 (704) 731-5900 www.meckabc.com Message from the Chairman & Chief

More information

National Dental Expenditure Flat Since 2008, Began to Slow in 2002

National Dental Expenditure Flat Since 2008, Began to Slow in 2002 National Dental Expenditure Flat Since 2008, Began to Slow in 2002 Author: Marko Vujicic, Ph.D. The Health Policy Institute (HPI) is a thought leader and trusted source for policy knowledge on critical

More information

Get the Facts: Minnesota s 2013 Tobacco Tax Increase is Improving Health

Get the Facts: Minnesota s 2013 Tobacco Tax Increase is Improving Health Get the Facts: Minnesota s 2013 Tobacco Tax Increase is Improving Health February 10, 2015 Lisa R. Mattson, MD Frank J. Chaloupka, PhD Raymond Boyle, PhD, MPH Overview The tobacco industry has a well-known

More information

Charitable Gambling Impact Study

Charitable Gambling Impact Study Charitable Gambling Impact Study A brief review of the fiscal impact of a statewide smoking ban on lawful gambling Presented by the Gambling Control Board (in cooperation with the Commissioner of Revenue)

More information

Alcohol Policy and Social Change: Creating Safer Community Environments James F. Mosher, JD Alcohol Policy Consultations

Alcohol Policy and Social Change: Creating Safer Community Environments James F. Mosher, JD Alcohol Policy Consultations Alcohol Policy and Social Change: Creating Safer Community Environments James F. Mosher, JD Alcohol Policy Consultations Statewide Summit: Transforming Ideas into Action Texas Standing Tall February 29,

More information

Tar and Nicotine. frbatlanta.org 23

Tar and Nicotine. frbatlanta.org 23 22 EconSouth Second Quarter 11 Tar and Nicotine Seeking any means available to raise revenue, southeastern states like their counterparts across the nation have been raising the tax rate on cigarettes,

More information

PROVIDING THE MONEY TO TRIPLE ARRESTS AND SUSTAIN ENHANCED DETERRENCE: A PROPOSAL FOR IMPROVING CONTROL OF THE DRINKING DRIVER SYNOPSIS

PROVIDING THE MONEY TO TRIPLE ARRESTS AND SUSTAIN ENHANCED DETERRENCE: A PROPOSAL FOR IMPROVING CONTROL OF THE DRINKING DRIVER SYNOPSIS PROVIDING THE MONEY TO TRIPLE ARRESTS AND SUSTAIN ENHANCED DETERRENCE: A PROPOSAL FOR IMPROVING CONTROL OF THE DRINKING DRIVER * F. Lowery SYNOPSIS Costs of controlling drinking drivers through the arrest/court

More information

n/e/r/a ALCOHOL IN LONDON: A COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS A Final Report for the Greater London Authority Prepared by NERA January 2003 London

n/e/r/a ALCOHOL IN LONDON: A COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS A Final Report for the Greater London Authority Prepared by NERA January 2003 London ALCOHOL IN LONDON: A COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS A Final Report for the Greater London Authority Prepared by NERA January 2003 London Project Team: Salman Aslam Leela Barham Edward Bramley-Harker John Dodgson

More information

SENATE, No STATE OF NEW JERSEY. 216th LEGISLATURE INTRODUCED JANUARY 30, 2014

SENATE, No STATE OF NEW JERSEY. 216th LEGISLATURE INTRODUCED JANUARY 30, 2014 SENATE, No. STATE OF NEW JERSEY th LEGISLATURE INTRODUCED JANUARY 0, 0 Sponsored by: Senator JOSEPH F. VITALE District (Middlesex) Senator LORETTA WEINBERG District (Bergen) SYNOPSIS Increases tobacco

More information

Controlling Cocaine: Supply Versus Demand Programs

Controlling Cocaine: Supply Versus Demand Programs Controlling Cocaine: Supply Versus Demand Programs C. Peter Rydell, Susan S. Everingham RAND Copyright 1994 Preface This report presents a model-based policy analysis of alternative methods of controlling

More information

1 Introduction There are health risks to people from excessive consumption of alcohol. Furthermore, excessive consumption can place a burden on society due to the cost of paying for healthcare and the

More information

Evidence-Based Policy Options To Reduce Prison Construction, Criminal Justice Costs, and Crime Rates

Evidence-Based Policy Options To Reduce Prison Construction, Criminal Justice Costs, and Crime Rates Evidence-Based Policy Options To Reduce Prison Construction, Criminal Justice Costs, and Crime Rates (Includes material from the Washington State Institute for Public Policy report, October, 2006) NCSL

More information

Nordic alcohol statistics

Nordic alcohol statistics Overview Nordic alcohol statistics 2010 2015 Nordic Studies on Alcohol and Drugs 2017, Vol. 34(3) 267 282 ª The Author(s) 2017 Reprints and permission: sagepub.co.uk/journalspermissions.nav DOI: 10.1177/1455072517719626

More information

An analysis of structural changes in the consumption patterns of beer, wine and spirits applying an alternative methodology

An analysis of structural changes in the consumption patterns of beer, wine and spirits applying an alternative methodology An analysis of structural changes in the consumption patterns of beer, wine and spirits applying an alternative methodology 1. Introduction Jan BENTZEN, Valdemar SMITH Department of Economics and Business

More information

1. This paper reports on the findings of the independent evaluation into the impact of the increases in tobacco excise duty.

1. This paper reports on the findings of the independent evaluation into the impact of the increases in tobacco excise duty. In-Confidence Office of the Associate Minister of Health Chair, Cabinet Social Wellbeing Committee FINDINGS OF THE EVALUATION OF TOBACCO EXCISE INCREASES Proposal 1. This paper reports on the findings

More information

Excellence in Prevention descriptions of the prevention

Excellence in Prevention descriptions of the prevention Name of Program/Strategy: Keg Registration Changing Conditions of Availability Report Contents 1. Overview and description 2. Implementation considerations (if available) 3. Descriptive information 4.

More information

ROMANIA. Upper-middle Income Data source: United Nations, data range

ROMANIA. Upper-middle Income Data source: United Nations, data range ROMANIA SOCIOECOMIC CONTEXT Total population 21,532,000 Annual population growth rate -0.5% Population 15+ years 85% Adult literacy rate 97.3% Population in urban areas 54% Income group (World bank) Upper-middle

More information

COMPREHENSIVE TOBACCO PREVENTION AND CESSATION PROGRAMS EFFECTIVELY REDUCE TOBACCO USE

COMPREHENSIVE TOBACCO PREVENTION AND CESSATION PROGRAMS EFFECTIVELY REDUCE TOBACCO USE COMPREHENSIVE TOBACCO PREVENTION AND CESSATION PROGRAMS EFFECTIVELY REDUCE TOBACCO USE Tobacco control programs play a crucial role in the prevention of many chronic conditions such as cancer, heart disease,

More information

COMPREHENSIVE TOBACCO PREVENTION AND CESSATION PROGRAMS EFFECTIVELY REDUCE TOBACCO USE

COMPREHENSIVE TOBACCO PREVENTION AND CESSATION PROGRAMS EFFECTIVELY REDUCE TOBACCO USE COMPREHENSIVE TOBACCO PREVENTION AND CESSATION PROGRAMS EFFECTIVELY REDUCE TOBACCO USE Tobacco control programs play a crucial role in the prevention of many chronic conditions such as cancer, heart disease,

More information

Minimum alcohol price policies in action: The Canadian Experience

Minimum alcohol price policies in action: The Canadian Experience Minimum alcohol price policies in action: The Canadian Experience Tim Stockwell, PhD Director, Centre for Addictions Research of BC Professor, Department of Psychology, University of Victoria Presentation

More information

Asia Illicit Tobacco Indicator 2016: Singapore. Prepared by Oxford Economics October 2017

Asia Illicit Tobacco Indicator 2016: Singapore. Prepared by Oxford Economics October 2017 Asia Illicit Tobacco Indicator 216: Singapore Prepared by Oxford Economics October 217 Disclaimer The Asia Illicit Tobacco Indicator 216 Report (the Report ) on the illicit tobacco trade in selected Asian

More information

The Economics of Smoking

The Economics of Smoking The Economics of Smoking One of the potential problems (from an economic perspective) with smoking is that there may be an externality in consumption, so there may be difference between the private and

More information

Alcohol in Ireland: Tackling the Financial Hangover

Alcohol in Ireland: Tackling the Financial Hangover Alcohol in Ireland: Tackling the Financial Hangover Pre Budget Submission 2011 & the Case for Minimum Pricing alcohol action ireland the national charity for alcohol-related issues www.alcoholireland.ie

More information

Alcohol Consumption and the Incidence of Acute Alcohol- Related Problems

Alcohol Consumption and the Incidence of Acute Alcohol- Related Problems Britiik Journal of AddUlum 79 il9s4) 173-180 1984 Society for tbe Study of Addictionto Alcohol and other Drugs Alcohol Consumption and the Incidence of Acute Alcohol- Related Problems Alexander C. Wagenaar,

More information

Alcohol taxes and restrictions could curb problem drinking, but are hard to sell

Alcohol taxes and restrictions could curb problem drinking, but are hard to sell 1 sur 5 20/11/2018 à 22:20 eu.usatoday.com Alcohol taxes and restrictions could curb problem drinking, but are hard to sell Jayne O'Donnell 8-10 minutes USA TODAY Published 6:17 PM EST Nov 19, 2018 When

More information

Fraser of Allander Institute

Fraser of Allander Institute Fraser of Allander Institute The economic impact of changes in alcohol consumption in the UK April 2018 Executive Summary The economic impact of changes in alcohol consumption in the UK The alcohol industry

More information

Alcohol Uncovered: Key Findings about the Use, Health Outcomes and Harm of Alcohol in Peel

Alcohol Uncovered: Key Findings about the Use, Health Outcomes and Harm of Alcohol in Peel 2015 Alcohol Uncovered: Key Findings about the Use, Health Outcomes and Harm of Alcohol in Peel Please use the following citation when referencing this document: Peel Public Health. Alcohol Uncovered:

More information

What's Happened to Dairy Product Sales and Why? by Karen Bunch a

What's Happened to Dairy Product Sales and Why? by Karen Bunch a What's Happened to Dairy Product Sales and Why? by Karen Bunch a Introduction Dairy products have historically been an important component of American diets. In terms of volume, more dairy products are

More information

TFI WHO 20 Avenue Appia 1211 Geneva 27, Switzerland. Gentlemen:

TFI WHO 20 Avenue Appia 1211 Geneva 27, Switzerland. Gentlemen: Donald D. Foreman, Director Federal Government Affairs 1455 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW, Suite 925 Washington, DC 20004 Telephone: (202) 626-7200 Fax: (202) 626-7208 TFI WHO 20 Avenue Appia 1211 Geneva 27,

More information