Intuitive Confidence and the Prominence Effect: When Consumer Choices are Sensitive to Matching Prices. Joseph P. Simmons Yale University

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Intuitive Confidence and the Prominence Effect: When Consumer Choices are Sensitive to Matching Prices. Joseph P. Simmons Yale University"

Transcription

1 1 Intuitive Confidence and the Prominence Effect: When Consumer Choices are Sensitive to Matching Prices Joseph P. Simmons Yale University Leif D. Nelson New York University Joseph P. Simmons is Assistant Professor of Marketing, Yale School of Management, 135 Prospect Street, New Haven, CT ( phone: ). Leif D. Nelson is Assistant Professor of Marketing, Stern School of Business, New York University, 40 West 4 th Street, New York, NY ( leifnelson@stern.nyu.edu; phone: ). The authors contributions to this article have been equated; author order is therefore irrelevant. The authors thank Ravi Dhar for commenting on a previous version of this manuscript. Portions of this research were presented at the 2006 Behavioral Decision Research in Management conference in Santa Monica, CA.

2 1 Intuitive Confidence and the Prominence Effect: When Consumer Choices are Sensitive to Matching Prices When choosing between equated alternatives, consumers choose the option that is superior on the most important dimension. In five studies, this prominence effect decreased as confidence in the prominent option s superiority (intuitive confidence) decreased. As intuitive confidence increased, deciding between equated alternatives became easy, and matching more poorly predicted choosing.

3 2 Imagine the following scenario. Due to a lapse in judgment, you find yourself signed up to participate in a laboratory study on consumer decision making. The experiment starts off by asking you to choose between two apartments that differ in quality. One apartment is clearly superior it dominates the other one and so you choose it. Next, the experimenter tells you that the inferior apartment costs $950 per month, and he asks you to set a price for the superior one that essentially renders you indifferent between the options. You oblige, and after setting a monthly price of $1500 for the superior apartment, he asks you to choose again in light of the two prices. Thus, you are forced to choose between two alternatives that you have equated in attractiveness. Now, ask yourself two questions. First, given this choice, which apartment would you select? Second, was this a hard decision? In trying to understand how people answer the first question, researchers have, seemingly quite sensibly, assumed that they already knew the answer to the second one. Choosing between equated alternatives must be a difficult thing to do because, well, the options are equated. Indeed, researchers have suggested that an operational definition of decision conflict is the degree of negative correlation between attributes (Luce 1998, p. 410). Thus, decisions are thought to be difficult to the extent that they require tradeoffs between attributes. Because equated alternatives represent choice options whose attributes are, for all practical purposes, perfectly negatively correlated, it seems sensible to conclude that choosing between equated alternatives arouses maximal choice conflict. Furthermore, with that as the premise, it seems reasonable to predict that consumers choices in this situation will resemble choices typically made under such conflict namely, consumers will rely on easy-to-justify tiebreaking strategies (Slovic 1975; Tversky, Sattath, and Slovic 1988) or, if possible, they will choose not to choose at all (Dhar 1997; Luce 1998; Tversky and Shafir 1992). In this paper, we propose an alternative account of how people choose between equated alternatives. The key differences between our account and existing theory are that (1) we propose that decision makers rely on metacognitive rather than justificatory reasons for choosing between equated alternatives, (2) we suggest that choosing between equated alternatives may actually feel easy, and (3) we reveal why it often feels easy, and we identify when it will feel difficult. With the research presented here, we hope to

4 3 increase researchers understanding of the causes and consequences of choice conflict, while explicating the conditions under which different methods of preference elicitation will diverge. From a practical standpoint, we hope to identify conditions under which willingness-to-pay responses will and will not predict choice shares. We begin by reviewing past research investigating choosing between equated alternatives. The Prominence Effect In the first investigation of choices between equated alternatives, Slovic (1975) presented people with two alternatives (e.g., Tire Brand A vs. Tire Brand B) that differed on two quantitative attribute dimensions (e.g., tread life vs. price). For one of the options an attribute value was missing, and participants filled it in with a number that made the options equally attractive to them (e.g., they filled in a missing price for Tire Brand A). Then, in a subsequent session, participants were asked to choose between the options that they had equated. Slovic found that, across many domains, people tended to choose the option that was superior on the most important, or prominent, dimension (Slovic 1975). For example, participants who equated the tire brands on the dimensions of price and tread life (the prominent dimension) subsequently chose the higher tread life tire over the cheaper tire 79% of the time. This finding is known as the prominence effect. 1 Building on Slovic s (1975) research, Tversky et al. (1988) found that, in general, people tend to more heavily weigh the prominent dimension in choice tasks than in matching/equating tasks (for replications and extensions, see Fischer, Carmon, Ariely, and Zauberman 1999; Fischer and Hawkins 1993; Selart 1996). In one oft-cited study, participants were presented with two transportation programs that varied on the dimensions of traffic casualties (the prominent dimension) and cost (Tversky, Sattath, and Slovic 1988, p. 373): 1 The prominence effect actually refers to two related but distinct effects in the literature. One is a between-subjects effect referring to the finding that people weigh the most important dimension more heavily in choice tasks than in matching tasks (Tversky et al. 1988). The other is a within-subjects effect referring to the finding that people tend to choose the option that is better on the most important dimension after they themselves have equated the options (Slovic 1975). In this manuscript, we refer mostly to this within-subjects prominence effect in our usage of this term. However, we do explore the between-subjects effect in the paper s final study, and we find that both effects are determined by similar processes.

5 4 Casualties Cost Program A 500 $55 million Program B 570 $12 million Program A cost more than Program B, but it also saved more lives. In one condition, participants were asked to choose between the two programs; in the other condition, they were asked to make the two programs equally attractive by filling in the missing cost value of Program A. When choosing between the options most participants (67%) selected Program A, the program with fewer casualties and a higher cost. However, in the matching condition, when the cost of Program A was unspecified, only 4% of respondents set an equating price as high as $55 million. Thus, the more prominent dimension (casualties) was given greater weight in choice than in matching. Researchers have offered a few different explanations for why people weigh the prominent dimension more heavily in choice than in matching (see Fischer, Carmon, Ariely, and Zauberman 1999 for a review). However, most treatments have focused on the vagaries of the matching process (e.g., Carmon and Simonson 1998; Fischer and Hawkins 1993; Frederick and Shafir 2006). Thus, despite some important distinctions, all of the explanations share the same assumption about how the choice process operates when people are confronted with equated alternatives. According to this assumption, people faced with equally-attractive alternatives choose the option that is superior on the prominent dimension (hereafter referred to as the prominent option) because choosing that option represents a choice strategy that is easy to implement and to justify (Bettman, Luce, and Payne 1998; Fischer, Carmon, Ariely, and Zauberman 1999; Selart 1996; Shafir, Simonson, and Tversky 1993; Slovic 1975, 1995; Tversky, Sattath, and Slovic 1988; see Table 1 for a summary of theorizing in support of this view). According to this view, choosing the prominent option is an explicit and sensible tiebreaking strategy that respondents employ when they are faced with such a difficult decision. As a result, we can expect consumers to choose the prominent option whenever they are faced with the choice between equated alternatives. This tiebreaking hypothesis has a lot of appeal, in no small part because it agrees with the widely accepted notion that people make difficult choices by using simplifying heuristics or choice strategies (e.g., Bettman et al. 1998; Frederick 2002; Kahneman and Frederick 2002; Tversky 1972; Tversky and

6 5 Shafir 1992). Indeed, there is considerable evidence demonstrating that people faced with difficult decisions tend to make choices based on reasons that are easy to justify (Shafir et al. 1993). Nevertheless, we contend that this hypothesis fails to capture how people make decisions between equated alternatives. Instead, we suggest that people faced with equated alternatives rely primarily on metacognitive rather than justificatory reasons for choosing between them. In particular, we argue that people often decide between equated options by choosing based on their feelings of confidence in the superiority of the prominent option. The more confidence people have in the prominent option s superiority, the more likely they are to choose it against an equated alternative. Thus, unlike the tiebreaking hypothesis, we predict that the prominence effect is not universal that it holds primarily when confidence in the superiority of the prominent option is high. In this light, we argue that the ubiquity of the prominence effect reflects a ubiquity in research design: Prominence effect researchers nearly always present participants with decisions that confer high confidence in the superiority of the prominent option. Indeed, most of this research has presented participants with 2 x 2 tables (like the one shown above) that feature two options that quantitatively differ along prominent and non-prominent attribute dimensions. In these situations, deciding which option is better on the prominent dimension is a simple matter of comparing the explicit prominent-option values, and the simplicity of this determination is likely to confer high confidence in the prominent option s superiority (e.g., I am confident that 570 casualties is worse than 500 casualties). By our account it is no surprise that the prominence effect is typically observed in such cases. Indeed, whenever consumers are highly confident that one option is better than another on the prominent dimension, we expect most consumers to choose that option. However, as we describe below, the malleability of the prominence effect becomes apparent when confidence in the prominent option s superiority is reduced. Intuitive Confidence and Choosing between Equated Alternatives People often answer difficult questions by first substituting and answering an easier one instead (Kahneman and Frederick 2002; Simmons and Nelson 2006). Consistent with this idea, our theory assumes that when choosing between equated alternatives, consumers attempt to answer a difficult

7 6 question (Given the options quality and price differences, should I choose option X?) by first answering an easier one that focuses on only one attribute dimension (Given the options quality difference, should I choose option X?). Thus, participants focus initially on the more important dimension (in this case, quality) at the expense of the less important dimension. The output of this initial assessment the prominent option serves as an initial hypothesis, or intuition, that they then assess in light of other attribute values that have not yet been considered. This subsequent assessment takes the form of a stayswitch decision: Consumers decide whether to stay with the intuitive, prominent option, or whether there is sufficient reason to switch away from that option and to choose the non-prominent alternative. Consistent with Simmons and Nelson (2006), we suggest that this stay-switch decision is determined in large part by intuitive confidence, which in this case refers to the consumer s subjective certainty that the prominent option is superior to its alternative. Consistent with a large body of research indicating that people rely on their feelings as information when making judgments and decisions (e.g., Schwarz 2004; Schwarz and Clore 1996), our account posits that intuitive confidence serves as metacognitive information that tells consumers whether they should stay with the prominent option in the face of an equated alternative. High intuitive confidence signals that this option should be chosen even in the face of an equated alternative. Low intuitive confidence, in contrast, signals that the non-intuitive alternative should receive more consideration, and that it should perhaps be chosen. Intuitive confidence, in turn, derives in large part from the ease with which people determine which option is better on the prominent dimension. The more easily people make this determination, the greater their intuitive confidence, and the more likely they will be to choose the prominent option in the face of an equated alternative (e.g., Epley and Norwick 2006; Kelley and Lindsay 1993). We refer to this prediction as the intuitive confidence hypothesis (Simmons and Nelson 2006), and it constitutes the first hypothesis of this paper: H 1 : The more confidence people have in the prominent option s superiority, the more likely they will be to choose it against an equated alternative.

8 7 Although rarely tested directly (for an exception, see Simmons and Nelson 2006, described below), the existing literature is consistent with the claim that intuitive confidence guides choices between equally attractive alternatives. At least three findings are relevant and supportive. First, Selart (1996) found that when options did not greatly differ along the prominent dimension, people were less likely to choose the prominent option over an equated alternative. Although Selart argued that this effect occurred because large prominent-attribute differences make tiebreaking choice strategies more salient than do small differences, it seems just as likely that larger differences inspire more confidence in the prominent option s superiority. Second, Heath and Tversky (1991) found that participants answering general knowledge questions preferred to bet on the accuracy of their own intuitive judgment rather than an equally-likely chance event when they were highly confident in their judgment, but not when they were less confident. For example, participants chose to bet on a judgment that they reportedly held with 90% confidence rather than a chance event that offered them a 90% chance of winning. However, this preference changed when subjective confidence was lower, as participants frequently chose to bet on the chance event when they were merely 55% confident in their own judgment and the chance event offered a 55% chance of victory. Heath and Tversky attributed this effect to people s desire to take credit for wins and to avoid taking blame for losses. In contrast, we believe that the effect may arise because high intuitive confidence encourages people to stay with their intuitions, whereas low confidence signals that the nonintuitive option (the chance event) should perhaps be chosen. Finally, Simmons and Nelson (2006) accumulated considerable support for the intuitive confidence hypothesis in their investigation of sporting event predictions. They showed that gamblers decisions between equated alternatives were based in large part on how confidently their intuitions favored one team over another. Specifically, they found that when one team was obviously better than another, participants believed that the superior team would win by a margin greater than their own predicted point differential. However, as it became more difficult to decide which team was better, participants were more likely to believe that the superior team would win by less than their predicted point differential.

9 8 Intuitive Confidence and Decision Conflict Because of the information that intuitive confidence provides to decision makers, we suggest that it determines not only choice outcomes but also whether a choice feels easy or difficult. Although common sense and past theorizing suggests that choosing between equated alternatives should always induce choice conflict, we propose here that the degree of choice conflict in this decision is actually determined by one s level of intuitive confidence. When it is easy to decide which option is superior, the high confidence that results provides an unambiguous prescription for how to choose in light of the equating prices (i.e., such high confidence tells consumers to stay with that initial option). In the face of such a straightforward prescription, we suggest that the final choice actually feels quite easy. However, when assessing the quality difference between two options feels difficult, the low confidence that results provides no obvious prescription for choosing against an equated, low-price alternative. Here a reliance on confidence tells consumers that the low-price alternative should be considered, and the choice is therefore difficult. This analysis agrees with Simmons and Nelson s (2006) intuitive betrayal hypothesis, which suggests that people are less satisfied with their choices when they betray their intuitions than when they choose consistently with them (for a conceptually related finding, see Kivetz and Simonson 2000). They found evidence for this effect even when intuitive options were objectively inferior, and decision confidence correlated negatively with decision accuracy under those circumstances. However, despite their strong evidence for the intuitive betrayal hypothesis, those researchers did not fully explain why intuitive options should be associated with greater decision satisfaction than equally attractive nonintuitive options. One possibility, in light of the preceding analysis, is that the effect arises because intuitive options are chosen only when intuitive confidence is high and when choosing feels easy, whereas nonintuitive options are chosen only when intuitive confidence is low and when choosing feels difficult. If people are more satisfied after making an easy choice than a difficult one precisely because they infer satisfaction from choice difficulty (i.e., Consumers feel satisfied with their choice because it was an easy one to make), then the fact that different options are chosen under different conditions of decision difficulty may explain

10 9 the intuitive betrayal effect. In tentative support of this notion, Simmons and Nelson did find that the intuitive betrayal effect was diminished after controlling for intuitive confidence, although the effect did persist in some cases. This discussion leads to our next hypothesis: H 2 : Consistent with Simmons and Nelson s (2006) intuitive betrayal hypothesis, people who choose the prominent option against an equated alternative will be more satisfied with their final choice than people who choose the non-prominent option. In addition, this effect should be at least partially mediated by intuitive confidence. Other hypotheses deriving from this analysis will be presented later in the paper. Research Overview In this paper, we report five studies exploring the effects of intuitive confidence on consumers decisions between equated alternatives. In most of these studies, participants assess two options on the prominent dimension of quality, equate the options on price, and then choose between the equated options. These studies go beyond previous research by revealing the choice processes underlying the prominence effect and by demonstrating that the prominence effect is not universal (Studies 1-3). In a further departure from previous research, we investigate whether intuitive confidence affects how much conflict people experience when choosing between equated alternatives, and we show that choosing between equated alternatives does not often feel difficult (Study 4). Finally, in Study 5, we explore for the first time whether these effects hold in a between-subjects investigation whether consumers willingness-to-pay match responses are more consistent with their choices when intuitive confidence is low than when it is high. Study 1a In Study 1a, we presented participants with a choice between two apartments that differed on the prominent dimension of quality (Carmon and Simonson 1998). In the Easy Choice condition, one apartment dominated the other it was superior on one dimension and identical on five other dimensions. In the Difficult Choice condition, each apartment was better on one feature (landlord quality), but worse

11 10 on another (available space). We expected the necessary tradeoff in the Difficult Choice condition to make choosing feel more difficult, and to reduce participants confidence in their preferred apartment. After choosing which apartment they preferred, participants indicated how much more money they would be willing to pay for their preference. Participants then imagined that their preferred apartment costs exactly that much more than the apartment they did not prefer, and they chose between the apartments given the equating price difference. Finally, participants indicated how satisfied they were with their final choice. Our hypotheses in this study, and in the subsequent studies, were consistent with our analysis of intuitive confidence and intuitive betrayal. We expected the prominence effect to be stronger in the Easy Choice condition than in the Difficult Choice condition (H 1 ). In addition, we expected participants to be more satisfied with their choices when they chose the prominent option than when they did not, and that this effect would be mediated by intuitive confidence (H 2 ). Method Participants. One hundred undergraduates participated in this experiment in exchange for partial course credit. We eliminated four participants who did not fully complete the task, leaving us with data from 96 participants in the analyses described below. Design. This study employed a simple two-group between-subjects design (Easy Choice vs. Difficult Choice). Procedure. Participants completed a one-page questionnaire at the beginning of a larger packet. Participants first imagined that they were considering renting an apartment and they identified which of two apartments listed on the page they would prefer to rent. In both conditions, the apartments were listed as Apartment A and Apartment B, and they were described along six attribute dimensions (neighborhood quality, landlord quality, quality of fixtures, amount of space, quality of neighbors, and distance from school). In the Easy Choice condition, Apartments A and B differed only on the attribute of landlord quality: Apartment B had a responsible landlord while Apartment A had an irresponsible landlord. In the Difficult Choice condition, the two apartments differed on two attributes: Apartment B had an

12 11 irresponsible landlord and a large space, while Apartment A had a responsible landlord and a small space. After choosing which apartment they preferred, participants were asked to indicate on a 9-point scale how confident they were that their choice was the right one (1 = not at all confident; 9 = very confident). We expected the majority of participants in both conditions to prefer Apartment B, and that this choice would be associated with less confidence in the Difficult Choice condition. Next, participants indicated how much more money per month they would be willing to spend for the apartment they preferred. Then, they were asked to imagine that the apartment that you did not select had a rent that was less than the preferred apartment by exactly the amount you just specified. Given the new difference in price, which apartment would you select? After making their selection, participants were asked two questions designed to assess decision satisfaction. The first question asked participants how satisfied they were with their choice. The second question asked participants to indicate how confident they were that their choice was the right one. Both questions were answered on 9-point scales anchored with 1 = not at all and 9 = very. The two decision satisfaction questions were very highly correlated (r =.81), and so we averaged them to create a single measure. Figure 1 presents a general outline of the methods employed in Studies 1-3. Results and Discussion Preliminary analyses confirmed the success of the manipulation. As shown in Table 2, participants in the Easy Choice condition were more likely to initially prefer Apartment B, and more confident in their initial preference (p s <.001). The effect of condition on confidence also held when selecting only participants who initially preferred Apartment B, as did every other effect that emerged in this study. Because this initial-choice variable had no effect on any of the results, we collapsed across this variable in the analyses described below. Although participants were more confident in their initial preference in the Easy Choice condition than in the Difficult Choice condition, the top half of Table 2 shows that participants were willing to pay significantly more for their preference in the Difficult Choice condition than in the Easy Choice condition. This presumably occurred because participants in the Difficult Choice condition tended to

13 12 choose based on an attribute that is traditionally tied to apartment prices (apartment size), whereas those in the Easy Choice condition chose based on an attribute that is not typically tied to price differences (landlord quality). Thus, although participants confidence ratings indicated a stronger, more certain initial preference in the Easy Choice condition, their pricings indicated a stronger initial preference in the Difficult Choice condition. This is an advantage of the current study because any effects of confidence on choosing between equated alternatives must be attributed to the confidence advantage that participants had in the Easy Choice condition, rather than to an overall strength-of-preference advantage, which is not evident in the pricings. Nevertheless, this conditional difference could be problematic if one assumes that participants will be more likely to choose against the prominent option when it is more highly priced. To get around this potential problem, we controlled for pricings in many of the analyses reported below. In addition, we eliminated or reversed this confound in subsequent studies. According to H 1, participants in the Easy Choice condition should be more likely than participants in the Difficult Choice condition to choose the prominent option over an equally attractive alternative. As shown in Table 2, this prediction was confirmed. In the Easy Choice condition 84.4% of participants stayed with their initial preference and chose the prominent option against an equated alternative. In contrast, only 54.9% of participants in the Difficult Choice condition made this choice. The prominence effect was significant in the Easy Choice condition, χ 2 (1, N = 45) = 21.36, p < 10-5, but not in the Difficult Choice condition, χ 2 (1, N = 51) = 0.49, p =.48. In a logistic regression, the effect of condition on choice was significant even after controlling for matching prices. Mediational analyses confirmed that intuitive confidence was responsible for the effect of condition on choice. Logistically regressing choice on (1) condition and (2) the measure of intuitive confidence produced only a significant effect of the intuitive confidence measure (p =.001); the effect of condition was non-significant (p =.32). Moreover, a Sobel test indicated that the inclusion of the intuitive confidence measure significantly reduced the effect of condition on prominent-option choosing, z = 2.89, p <.004. These results did not differ when controlling for the magnitude of equating prices.

14 13 A t-test analyzing the effects of prominent-option choosing on decision satisfaction revealed strong support for H 2 as well. Participants who chose the prominent option were much more satisfied with their choice (M = 6.52) than were participants who chose the non-prominent option (M = 5.13), t(93) = 3.90, p <.001. A 2-way Condition x Choice ANOVA revealed that this effect was of a similar magnitude in both choice conditions (i.e., the interaction was nonsignificant: p =.375). Also, as expected, a linear regression revealed that the effect of choice on decision satisfaction reduced to marginal significance (p =.053) when controlling for intuitive confidence, which significantly predicted decision satisfaction (p =.002). A Sobel test indicated that this reduction was highly significant, z = 2.78, p <.006. This suggests that the effect of choice on decision satisfaction was at least partially attributable to the effect of intuitive confidence on prominent-option choosing. The results of this study support the notion that increased intuitive confidence increases prominent-option choosing and decision satisfaction. Study 1b In Study 1a, participants choosing between equated alternatives were less likely to choose the highquality prominent option when the initial quality assessment was difficult and associated with low confidence than when it was easy and associated with high confidence. Indeed, the prominence effect was obtained only in the Easy Choice condition. In Study 1b, we sought to demonstrate that this effect would still emerge when participants were not asked to explicitly choose between the two options on the dimension of quality or to indicate their confidence in their initial choice before choosing between the equated alternatives. In addition, we sought to replicate Study 1a when the method of equating the alternatives required participants to set prices for the options rather than indicating an equating price difference. Method Participants. Two hundred and twenty-eight undergraduates participated in exchange for a chance to win a $50 prize. Design. This study featured a simple two-group design identical to the design of Study 1a (i.e., Easy Choice condition vs. Difficult Choice condition).

15 14 Procedure. As part of a web survey, participants completed a one-page questionnaire that began by asking them to consider two apartments Apartment X and Apartment Y. The features of the apartments were identical to Study 1a, as were the easy vs. difficult choice manipulations. Apartment X was identical to Apartment A in Study 1a, while Apartment Y was identical to Study 1a s Apartment B. Below the listing of the apartments features, participants were asked to Assume that Apartment X costs $1350 per month. What monthly rent would make Apartment Y equally attractive to Apartment X? Thus, unlike Study 1a, participants did not first choose between the options or rate their confidence in this choice before matching them on price. Further, the matching task asked participants to indicate an exact price for Apartment Y rather than a price differential. After setting a price for Apartment Y, participants were asked to imagine that Apartment Y was renting for exactly the amount they had just specified, and to then choose between the apartments. After making their choice, participants indicated their satisfaction with that choice using the same two items and scales as in Study 1a. These two items were once again very highly correlated (r =.71), and so we averaged them to create a single measure of decision satisfaction. Results and Discussion Despite the methodological differences between Studies 1a and 1b, the bottom half of Table 2 reveals that Study 1b replicated the findings of Study 1a. Consistent with H 1, 77.6% of participants in the Easy Choice condition stayed with their initial preference and chose the prominent option against an equated alternative. In contrast, only 46.4% of participants in the Difficult Choice condition stayed with their initial choice. Thus, the prominence effect held in the Easy Choice condition, χ 2 (1, N = 116) = 35.31, p < 10-8, but not in the Difficult Choice condition, χ 2 (1, N = 112) = 0.57, p = 45. In a logistic regression, the effect of condition on prominent-option choosing remained significant after controlling for matching prices (p <.0001), which were once again greater in the Difficult Choice than Easy Choice condition, t(226) = 3.07, p =.002. In support of H 2, participants were vastly more satisfied with their final choice when they chose in line with their initial, quality-based preference (M = 6.29) than when switching to the better-priced option

16 15 (M = 5.28), t(226) = 4.04, p < Somewhat surprisingly, however, a 2-way Condition x Choice ANOVA revealed a significant Choice X Condition interaction, F(1, 224) = 14.23, p <.001. The effect of choice on decision satisfaction was evident only in the Easy Choice condition, but not in the Difficult Choice condition. This result is inconsistent with Study 1a, and with the results of similar studies (Simmons and Nelson 2006). Thus, we assume it is anomalous, and we do not discuss it further. Studies 1a and 1b provided strong support for all three hypotheses. Participants in the Easy Choice condition were more confident in their initial quality-based preference than participants in the Difficult Choice condition. As a result, they were much more likely to select the same high-quality option when choosing against an equated alternative, and they were more satisfied with their final choice. Further, Study 1b demonstrated that these effects emerged even when participants were not required to explicitly choose between the options before pricing them, even when they did not rate how confident they were in their initial preference, and even when the matching task required them to set specific prices for one of the apartments rather than indicating a price differential. Thus, we can be confident that the validity of our hypotheses is not dependent on any of these methodological factors. Study 2 The results of Study 1 suggest that intuitive confidence plays an important role in the production of the prominence effect. Indeed, when intuitive confidence was decreased by making the quality difference between the options more difficult to discern, the prominence effect disappeared an effect that was mediated by intuitive confidence in the only study that measured it (Study 1a). In Study 2, we attempted to extend these findings to a different manipulation of intuitive confidence, while ruling out the relevance of two confounds of Study 1: (1) the fact that the choice options had different values on the critical attributes across the two conditions (i.e., landlord quality was high for the prominent option in the Easy Condition, but lower for the most prevalent prominent option in the Difficult Choice condition), and (2) the fact that the confidence manipulation required a tradeoff between quality attributes in one condition but not the other. In Study 2, we avoided these confounds by manipulating intuitive confidence in a way that did not alter the choice options themselves.

17 16 All participants in Study 2 were first presented with a simple choice between two existing car brands Nissan vs. Mazda. Unlike Studies 1a and 1b, the options were presented without attributes so that the initial choice task required a simple declaration of existing preferences. After they indicated their preference we manipulated intuitive confidence. We induced high intuitive confidence by asking approximately half of the participants to list two reasons for their preference. The remaining participants were asked to list 10 reasons. In these tasks, people typically find it relatively easy to list two reasons for their preferences, and that feeling of ease confers them with high confidence in their choices. However, people find it relatively difficult to list 10 reasons, and that feeling of difficulty confers a lack of confidence in their choices. Thus, asking participants to list ten reasons for a choice can decrease confidence in that choice. This manipulation is based on the influential work of Schwarz, Bless, Strack, Klumpp, Rittenauer-Schatka, and Simons (1991), who showed that people rely on the ease vs. difficulty of generating reasons in order to infer aspects of their own personalities, among other things (see Schwarz 2004, for a review). If the List 2 Reasons vs. List 10 Reasons manipulation results in the same effects observed in Studies 1a and 1b, then we can be confident that those results were attributable not to condition differences in the choice stimuli, but to the effects of intuitive confidence on choosing between equated alternatives. Method Participants. One hundred and twenty-eight undergraduates participated in this study in exchange for course credit. Of these, six participants were removed for indicating equating price differences equal to zero, and three were removed for failing to complete the task. This left data from 119 participants for the final analyses. Design. This study employed a simple two-group between-subjects design (List 2 Reasons vs. List 10 Reasons). Procedure. As part of a laboratory session, participants completed a one-page questionnaire that began by asking them to indicate which of two brands of cars they preferred, Mazda or Nissan. After indicating their preference, participants were either asked to list two reasons for their preference (the List

18 17 2 Reasons condition) or to list ten reasons for their preference (the List 10 Reasons condition). Next, participants were asked to indicate their preference on a 10-point scale where 1 = Strongly prefer the Mazda, 5 = Slightly prefer the Mazda, 6 = Slightly prefer the Nissan, and 10 = Strongly prefer the Nissan. They then indicated how certain they were in their preference on a 10-point scale ranging from 1 = Not at all certain to 10 = Completely certain. Next, participants were asked to indicate how much more they would be willing to spend for the car they preferred. They were then asked to imagine that your preferred car costs exactly that much more than your unpreferred car. At these new prices, which car would you select? Express your preference in light of this additional cost. Participants then expressed their preference on the same 10-point preference scale that they had used previously. Finally, participants indicated how certain they were in this final preference and how satisfied they were with their purchase decision. These two items were highly correlated (r =.79), and so we averaged them to create a composite measure of decision satisfaction. Results and Discussion Preliminary analyses confirmed the success of the manipulation. As shown in Table 3, participants in the List 2 Reasons condition were more confident in their initial preference than were participants in the List 10 Reasons condition, t(117) = 3.15, p =.002. In order to investigate the effects of our manipulation on choices, we computed the percentage of participants who stayed with vs. switched away from their initial preference in the face of equating prices. In support of H 1, we found that participants in the List 2 Reasons condition were significantly more likely to stay with their initial preference when choosing against an equated alternative (82.8%) than were participants in the List 10 Reasons condition (57.4%), χ 2 (1, N = 119) = 9.08, p <.003. The prominence effect was significant in the List 2 Reasons condition, χ 2 (1, N = 58) = 24.90, p < 10-6, but not in the List 10 Reasons condition, χ 2 (1, N = 61) = 1.33, p <.25. This difference arose despite the lack of condition differences in which option was initially preferred (p =.86) and in the magnitude of the equating prices (p =.45). Moreover, this difference also emerged when we treated preference change as a continuous variable rather than as a dichotomous choice variable: In the face of equating prices, participants in the

19 18 List 2 reasons condition altered their preference more toward the low-quality, low-price option than did participants in the List 10 Reasons condition, t(117) = 2.44, p <.02, an effect that held when controlling for the magnitude of equating prices (p <.03). The relevant means are displayed in Table 3. In further support of H 1, mediational analyses suggest that intuitive confidence was responsible for the effect of listing reasons on choice. Logistically regressing choice on (1) condition and (2) the measure of intuitive confidence produced only a significant positive relation between the intuitive confidence measure and prominent-option choosing (p <.001); the effect of condition was only marginally significant (p =.082). Moreover, a Sobel test showed that the inclusion of the intuitive confidence measure reduced the effect of condition on prominent-option choosing, z = 2.57, p =.01. These results did not differ when controlling for the magnitude of equating prices. This study also produced the expected effects of choice and condition on decision satisfaction. Consistent with H 2, participants were much more satisfied with their final decisions when they stayed with their initial preference than when they switched to the alternative, t(117) = 3.70, p <.001. A 2-way Condition x Choice ANOVA revealed that this effect was of a similar magnitude in both choice conditions (i.e., the interaction was nonsignificant: p =.89). Moreover, when we regressed decision satisfaction on both choice (stay vs. switch) and intuitive confidence, the effect of choice became nonsignificant (p <.40) and was significantly reduced, z = 5.35, p < The effect of intuitive confidence on decision satisfaction was highly significant, p < Study 2 produced evidence consistent with our hypotheses by manipulating confidence in a way that did not alter the choice options themselves. These findings suggest that the results of Studies 1a and 1b were not attributable to the confounds discussed earlier, but rather to the hypothesized effects of intuitive confidence on prominent-option choosing. People who are confident in the quality superiority of their chosen option are more likely to choose that option again in the face of an equated alternative, and they are also more satisfied with their final decision. This occurs even when confidence is decreased by searching for too many reasons for one s preference. Study 3

20 19 Study 3 sought to test our hypotheses by relying on a different manipulation of intuitive confidence that once again failed to alter the relevant aspects of the decision context the font of the questionnaire. Researchers have demonstrated that people often infer their own level of confidence in answers to questions based on the ease with which they answer those questions (Epley and Norwick 2006; Kelley and Lindsay 1993). When they feel that answering a question is difficult, they assume that they have low confidence in their answer. When they feel that answering it is easy, they assume that they have high confidence in their answer. As a result, manipulations that decrease the ease of answering a question can without changing decision accuracy decrease the confidence people have in their answer. One such manipulation is font. Texts that appear in bad font are more difficult to read, and people often infer from this difficulty that they are less confident in answers given to questions written in bad font even though bad fonts do not affect answer quality or accuracy (Novemsky, Dhar, Schwarz, and Simonson, forthcoming; Simmons and Nelson, 2006). Essentially, people misattribute reading difficulty to question difficulty, and they consequently lack confidence in their answers to questions written in a bad font. However, if the source of the uncertainty is clarified with a warning that the font may disrupt their processing, people do accurately attribute processing difficulty to the poor font, and their inferences of confidence are therefore unaffected by the font (Novemsky et al., forthcoming). In Study 3, participants made an easy choice between two apartments one apartment dominated the other on a questionnaire that was printed in either easy-to-read font or difficult-to-read font. In addition, within the Bad Font condition, participants were either warned about the bad font or not. As in Studies 1a and 1b, participants matched the apartments on price after choosing between them, chose again, and then indicated how satisfied they were with their final decision. We expected the difficult-to-read font to decrease participants confidence in their preference, but only when they were not warned about the font. As a result, we expected decreased prominent-option choosing, and therefore decreased decision satisfaction, in the Bad Font Unwarned condition than in the Good Font or Bad Font Warned conditions. Method

21 20 Participants. Sixty-four undergraduates participated in this study in exchange for course credit. Two participants were eliminated for indicating equating price differences equal to zero, thus leaving 62 participants for the final analyses. Design. This study employed a three-group between-subjects design (Good Font vs. Bad Font Warned vs. Bad Font Unwarned). Procedure. As part of a larger experimental session, participants completed a one-page questionnaire that was identical in content to the Easy Choice condition of Study 1a. Participants chose between two apartments Apartment A vs. Apartment B in a situation where Apartment B dominated Apartment A. They then indicated how confident they were in this choice before equating the options by setting a price differential and then choosing again between the equated options. They completed the questionnaire by indicating how satisfied they were with their final decision. The only difference between the procedures of Study 1a s Easy Choice condition and Study 3 was in the critical manipulation employed in Study 3, which involved presenting the questionnaire in different fonts. In the Good Font condition, the questionnaire was printed in easy-to-read Times New Roman 12- point font. In the two Bad Font conditions, the questionnaire was printed in difficult-to-read 10-point Haettenschweiler italicized font. Participants in the Bad Font Unwarned condition received no warning about the font, whereas participants in the Bad Font Warned condition were warned at the top of the questionnaire in easy-to-read 13-point Century Gothic bold italicized font with an apology that read: Sorry about the font. We are having trouble with the software. 2 Results and Discussion The manipulation significantly affected intuitive confidence, F(2, 59) = 3.78, p <.03. As predicted, participants in the Bad Font Unwarned condition were less confident in the superiority of the prominent option than those in the Good Font and Bad Font Warned conditions, t(59) = 2.67, p =.01. In addition, 2 The astute reader will realize that this should have made little sense to the participants, because the apology for the bad font was actually printed in good font. Nevertheless, participants indicated no suspicion about this warning, adding yet another example to the catalog of demonstrations that people are often mindless in their intake of information (e.g., Langer, Blank, and Chanowitz 1978).

22 21 the font manipulation affected confidence without affecting matching prices, F(2, 59) = 1.73, p <.19. See Table 4 for the relevant means and choice percentages. In support of H 1, participants in the Bad Font Unwarned condition were less likely to choose the prominent option in the face of an equated alternative than were participants in either the Good Font condition, χ 2 (1, N = 42) = 3.86, p <.05, or the Bad Font Warned condition, χ 2 (1, N = 41) = 5.03, p <.03. Further, the prominence effect was significant in the Good Font, χ 2 (1, N = 21) = 8.05, p <.005, and Bad Font Warned conditions, χ 2 (1, N = 20) = 9.80, p <.002, but not in the Bad Font Unwarned condition, χ 2 (1, N = 21) = 0.05, p =.83. As Table 4 reveals, the ordering of the choice percentages across the three conditions matched the ordering of confidence across the conditions. Further, the correlation between intuitive confidence and prominent-option choosing was once again strongly positive and highly significant, r(60) =.47, p <.001, and this effect held when controlling for matching prices, r(59) =.54, p <.001. Mediational analyses showed that controlling for intuitive confidence reduced the effect of font on prominent-option choosing, z = 1.94, p <.053, a result that became a little stronger (p <.043) after controlling for matching prices. All in all, then, these results provide strong support for the hypothesized effects of intuitive confidence on choice. Supporting H 2, participants were once again much more satisfied with their decision when they stayed with the prominent option in the face of equating prices than when they switched to the non-prominent option, t(60) = 5.88, p < Once again, this effect of choice on decision satisfaction was significantly reduced when controlling for intuitive confidence, z = 3.26, p <.002, though both variables remained significant predictors of satisfaction (p s <.001). Consistent with Simmons and Nelson (2006) and with Study 1a, this result suggests that the intuitive betrayal effect is determined in part but not entirely by intuitive confidence. In sum, the results of Study 3 found evidence for both hypotheses. Even when intuitive confidence is manipulated by altering the font of the questionnaire (and nothing else), increased confidence is associated with increased prominent-option choosing and increased decision satisfaction. The fact that our hypotheses were most strongly evident in the differences between the two Bad Font conditions rules out

Intuitive Confidence Reflects Speed of Initial Responses in Point Spread Predictions. Alexander C. Walker. A thesis

Intuitive Confidence Reflects Speed of Initial Responses in Point Spread Predictions. Alexander C. Walker. A thesis Intuitive Confidence Reflects Speed of Initial Responses in Point Spread Predictions by Alexander C. Walker A thesis presented to the University of Waterloo in fulfilment of the thesis requirement for

More information

The Influence of Hedonic versus Utilitarian Consumption Goals on the Compromise Effect. Abstract

The Influence of Hedonic versus Utilitarian Consumption Goals on the Compromise Effect. Abstract The Influence of Hedonic versus Utilitarian Consumption Goals on the Compromise Effect Abstract This article reports the effects of hedonic versus utilitarian consumption goals on consumers choices between

More information

Introduction to Preference and Decision Making

Introduction to Preference and Decision Making Introduction to Preference and Decision Making Psychology 466: Judgment & Decision Making Instructor: John Miyamoto 10/31/2017: Lecture 06-1 Note: This Powerpoint presentation may contain macros that I

More information

Comparative Ignorance and the Ellsberg Paradox

Comparative Ignorance and the Ellsberg Paradox The Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 22:2; 129 139, 2001 2001 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Manufactured in The Netherlands. Comparative Ignorance and the Ellsberg Paradox CLARE CHUA CHOW National University

More information

Consumers can make purchase decisions by choosing or

Consumers can make purchase decisions by choosing or Choice, Rejection, and Elaboration on Preference-Inconsistent Alternatives JULIANO LARAN KEITH WILCOX Previous research has demonstrated that rejecting product alternatives (i.e., choosing which alternatives

More information

Choosing versus Rejecting: The Impact of Goal-Task Compatibility on Decision Confidence

Choosing versus Rejecting: The Impact of Goal-Task Compatibility on Decision Confidence CHERNEV GOAL-TASK COMPATIBILITY AND DECISION PROCESSES Social Cognition, Vol. 27, No. 2, 2009, pp. 249 260 Choosing versus Rejecting: The Impact of Goal-Task Compatibility on Decision Confidence Alexander

More information

The Effect of Accuracy Motivation on Anchoring and Adjustment: Do People Adjust from Provided Anchors?

The Effect of Accuracy Motivation on Anchoring and Adjustment: Do People Adjust from Provided Anchors? University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Marketing Papers Wharton Faculty Research 12-2010 The Effect of Accuracy Motivation on Anchoring and Adjustment: Do People Adjust from Provided Anchors? Joseph

More information

The Instrumentality Heuristic

The Instrumentality Heuristic PSYCHOLOGICAL SCIENCE Research Article The Instrumentality Heuristic Why Metacognitive Difficulty Is Desirable During Goal Pursuit Aparna A. Labroo and Sara Kim University of Chicago ABSTRACT The literature

More information

Recognizing Ambiguity

Recognizing Ambiguity Recognizing Ambiguity How Lack of Information Scares Us Mark Clements Columbia University I. Abstract In this paper, I will examine two different approaches to an experimental decision problem posed by

More information

Experimental Testing of Intrinsic Preferences for NonInstrumental Information

Experimental Testing of Intrinsic Preferences for NonInstrumental Information Experimental Testing of Intrinsic Preferences for NonInstrumental Information By Kfir Eliaz and Andrew Schotter* The classical model of decision making under uncertainty assumes that decision makers care

More information

Consider the following scenario: A consumer is deciding

Consider the following scenario: A consumer is deciding The Impact of Common Features on Consumer Preferences: A Case of Confirmatory Reasoning ALEXANDER CHERNEV* This article examines how confirmatory reasoning moderates the impact of attractive and unattractive

More information

Title: Healthy snacks at the checkout counter: A lab and field study on the impact of shelf arrangement and assortment structure on consumer choices

Title: Healthy snacks at the checkout counter: A lab and field study on the impact of shelf arrangement and assortment structure on consumer choices Author's response to reviews Title: Healthy snacks at the checkout counter: A lab and field study on the impact of shelf arrangement and assortment structure on consumer choices Authors: Ellen van Kleef

More information

MCAS Equating Research Report: An Investigation of FCIP-1, FCIP-2, and Stocking and. Lord Equating Methods 1,2

MCAS Equating Research Report: An Investigation of FCIP-1, FCIP-2, and Stocking and. Lord Equating Methods 1,2 MCAS Equating Research Report: An Investigation of FCIP-1, FCIP-2, and Stocking and Lord Equating Methods 1,2 Lisa A. Keller, Ronald K. Hambleton, Pauline Parker, Jenna Copella University of Massachusetts

More information

Why do Psychologists Perform Research?

Why do Psychologists Perform Research? PSY 102 1 PSY 102 Understanding and Thinking Critically About Psychological Research Thinking critically about research means knowing the right questions to ask to assess the validity or accuracy of a

More information

Risky Choice Decisions from a Tri-Reference Point Perspective

Risky Choice Decisions from a Tri-Reference Point Perspective Academic Leadership Journal in Student Research Volume 4 Spring 2016 Article 4 2016 Risky Choice Decisions from a Tri-Reference Point Perspective Kevin L. Kenney Fort Hays State University Follow this

More information

Sawtooth Software. The Number of Levels Effect in Conjoint: Where Does It Come From and Can It Be Eliminated? RESEARCH PAPER SERIES

Sawtooth Software. The Number of Levels Effect in Conjoint: Where Does It Come From and Can It Be Eliminated? RESEARCH PAPER SERIES Sawtooth Software RESEARCH PAPER SERIES The Number of Levels Effect in Conjoint: Where Does It Come From and Can It Be Eliminated? Dick Wittink, Yale University Joel Huber, Duke University Peter Zandan,

More information

Magnitude and accuracy differences between judgements of remembering and forgetting

Magnitude and accuracy differences between judgements of remembering and forgetting THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF EXPERIMENTAL PSYCHOLOGY 2012, 65 (11), 2231 2257 Magnitude and accuracy differences between judgements of remembering and forgetting Michael J. Serra and Benjamin D. England Department

More information

Examples of Feedback Comments: How to use them to improve your report writing. Example 1: Compare and contrast

Examples of Feedback Comments: How to use them to improve your report writing. Example 1: Compare and contrast Examples of Feedback Comments: How to use them to improve your report writing This document contains 4 examples of writing and feedback comments from Level 2A lab reports, and 4 steps to help you apply

More information

It is Whether You Win or Lose: The Importance of the Overall Probabilities of Winning or Losing in Risky Choice

It is Whether You Win or Lose: The Importance of the Overall Probabilities of Winning or Losing in Risky Choice The Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 30:1; 5 19, 2005 c 2005 Springer Science + Business Media, Inc. Manufactured in The Netherlands. It is Whether You Win or Lose: The Importance of the Overall Probabilities

More information

Assignment 4: True or Quasi-Experiment

Assignment 4: True or Quasi-Experiment Assignment 4: True or Quasi-Experiment Objectives: After completing this assignment, you will be able to Evaluate when you must use an experiment to answer a research question Develop statistical hypotheses

More information

Chapter 11 Decision Making. Syllogism. The Logic

Chapter 11 Decision Making. Syllogism. The Logic Chapter 11 Decision Making Syllogism All men are mortal. (major premise) Socrates is a man. (minor premise) (therefore) Socrates is mortal. (conclusion) The Logic Mortal Socrates Men 1 An Abstract Syllogism

More information

Thank you very much for your guidance on this revision. We look forward to hearing from you.

Thank you very much for your guidance on this revision. We look forward to hearing from you. 1 PAINTED BUNTING MANUSCRIPT REVIEW HISTORY REVISION NOTES FROM AUTHORS (ROUND 2) We would like to submit a revision of our manuscript. As you requested, we have run new studies that employ additional

More information

Intuitive Confidence: Choosing Between Intuitive and Nonintuitive Alternatives

Intuitive Confidence: Choosing Between Intuitive and Nonintuitive Alternatives Journal of Experimental Psychology: General Copyright 2006 by the American Psychological Association 2006, Vol. 135, No. 3, 409 428 0096-3445/06/$12.00 DOI: 10.1037/0096-3445.135.3.409 Intuitive Confidence:

More information

The Influence of Framing Effects and Regret on Health Decision-Making

The Influence of Framing Effects and Regret on Health Decision-Making Colby College Digital Commons @ Colby Honors Theses Student Research 2012 The Influence of Framing Effects and Regret on Health Decision-Making Sarah Falkof Colby College Follow this and additional works

More information

Evaluating the Causal Role of Unobserved Variables

Evaluating the Causal Role of Unobserved Variables Evaluating the Causal Role of Unobserved Variables Christian C. Luhmann (christian.luhmann@vanderbilt.edu) Department of Psychology, Vanderbilt University 301 Wilson Hall, Nashville, TN 37203 USA Woo-kyoung

More information

Interpreting Instructional Cues in Task Switching Procedures: The Role of Mediator Retrieval

Interpreting Instructional Cues in Task Switching Procedures: The Role of Mediator Retrieval Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition 2006, Vol. 32, No. 3, 347 363 Copyright 2006 by the American Psychological Association 0278-7393/06/$12.00 DOI: 10.1037/0278-7393.32.3.347

More information

UNIVERSITY OF DUBLIN TRINITY COLLEGE. Faculty of Arts Humanities and Social Sciences. School of Business

UNIVERSITY OF DUBLIN TRINITY COLLEGE. Faculty of Arts Humanities and Social Sciences. School of Business UNIVERSITY OF DUBLIN TRINITY COLLEGE Faculty of Arts Humanities and Social Sciences School of Business M.Sc. (Finance) Degree Examination Michaelmas 2011 Behavioural Finance Monday 12 th of December Luce

More information

Gamble Evaluation and Evoked Reference Sets: Why Adding a Small Loss to a Gamble Increases Its Attractiveness. Draft of August 20, 2016

Gamble Evaluation and Evoked Reference Sets: Why Adding a Small Loss to a Gamble Increases Its Attractiveness. Draft of August 20, 2016 Evoked Reference Sets -- 1 Gamble Evaluation and Evoked Reference Sets: Why Adding a Small Loss to a Gamble Increases Its Attractiveness Craig R. M. McKenzie UC San Diego Shlomi Sher Pomona College Draft

More information

Explaining outcome type interactions with frame: Aspiration level and the value function

Explaining outcome type interactions with frame: Aspiration level and the value function Memory & Cognition 28, 36 (4), 838-848 doi: 1.3758/MC.36.4.838 Explaining outcome type interactions with frame: Aspiration level and the value function AMBER N. BLOOMFIELD DePaul University, Chicago, Illinois

More information

EUNICE Y. KIM June 2009

EUNICE Y. KIM June 2009 EUNICE Y. KIM June 2009 Yale School of Management 135 Prospect Street, New Haven, CT 06520-8200 Tel: (610) 324-6803 eunice.kim@yale.edu http://elab.som.yale.edu/eunice/eyk/research.htm EDUCATION Ph.D.,

More information

Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes

Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes (0) Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/obhdp

More information

Further Properties of the Priority Rule

Further Properties of the Priority Rule Further Properties of the Priority Rule Michael Strevens Draft of July 2003 Abstract In Strevens (2003), I showed that science s priority system for distributing credit promotes an allocation of labor

More information

7 Action. 7.1 Choice. Todd Davies, Decision Behavior: Theory and Evidence (Spring 2010) Version: June 4, 2010, 2:40 pm

7 Action. 7.1 Choice. Todd Davies, Decision Behavior: Theory and Evidence (Spring 2010) Version: June 4, 2010, 2:40 pm 7 Action Todd Davies, Decision Behavior: Theory and Evidence (Spring 2010) We can now apply beliefs, preferences, and confidence to choices between different possible actions or options. 7.1 Choice DEFINITION

More information

ABSTRACT. Professor Dr. Rebecca Hamilton and Professor Dr. Joydeep Srivastava, Department of Marketing

ABSTRACT. Professor Dr. Rebecca Hamilton and Professor Dr. Joydeep Srivastava, Department of Marketing ABSTRACT Title of Document: THE INFLUENCE OF CONSUMER MOTIVATIONS ON CONSUMPTION INTENTIONS AND BEHAVIOR Francine da Silveira Espinoza, Doctor of Philosophy, 2009 Co-Directed By: Professor Dr. Rebecca

More information

Attentional Theory Is a Viable Explanation of the Inverse Base Rate Effect: A Reply to Winman, Wennerholm, and Juslin (2003)

Attentional Theory Is a Viable Explanation of the Inverse Base Rate Effect: A Reply to Winman, Wennerholm, and Juslin (2003) Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition 2003, Vol. 29, No. 6, 1396 1400 Copyright 2003 by the American Psychological Association, Inc. 0278-7393/03/$12.00 DOI: 10.1037/0278-7393.29.6.1396

More information

Focusing on Desirability: The Effect of Decision Interruption and Suspension on Preferences WENDY LIU*

Focusing on Desirability: The Effect of Decision Interruption and Suspension on Preferences WENDY LIU* 1 Focusing on Desirability: The Effect of Decision Interruption and Suspension on Preferences WENDY LIU* 2 *Wendy Liu is Assistant Professor of Marketing at the UCLA Anderson School of Management, 110

More information

Some Thoughts on the Principle of Revealed Preference 1

Some Thoughts on the Principle of Revealed Preference 1 Some Thoughts on the Principle of Revealed Preference 1 Ariel Rubinstein School of Economics, Tel Aviv University and Department of Economics, New York University and Yuval Salant Graduate School of Business,

More information

Choice set options affect the valuation of risky prospects

Choice set options affect the valuation of risky prospects Choice set options affect the valuation of risky prospects Stian Reimers (stian.reimers@warwick.ac.uk) Neil Stewart (neil.stewart@warwick.ac.uk) Nick Chater (nick.chater@warwick.ac.uk) Department of Psychology,

More information

The Good, the Bad and the Blameworthy: Understanding the Role of Evaluative Reasoning in Folk Psychology. Princeton University

The Good, the Bad and the Blameworthy: Understanding the Role of Evaluative Reasoning in Folk Psychology. Princeton University The Good, the Bad and the Blameworthy: Understanding the Role of Evaluative Reasoning in Folk Psychology Joshua Knobe Gabriel Mendlow Princeton University People ordinarily make sense of their own behavior

More information

THE INTERPRETATION OF EFFECT SIZE IN PUBLISHED ARTICLES. Rink Hoekstra University of Groningen, The Netherlands

THE INTERPRETATION OF EFFECT SIZE IN PUBLISHED ARTICLES. Rink Hoekstra University of Groningen, The Netherlands THE INTERPRETATION OF EFFECT SIZE IN PUBLISHED ARTICLES Rink University of Groningen, The Netherlands R.@rug.nl Significance testing has been criticized, among others, for encouraging researchers to focus

More information

Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition

Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition Conflict and Bias in Heuristic Judgment Sudeep Bhatia Online First Publication, September 29, 2016. http://dx.doi.org/10.1037/xlm0000307

More information

Confidence in Sampling: Why Every Lawyer Needs to Know the Number 384. By John G. McCabe, M.A. and Justin C. Mary

Confidence in Sampling: Why Every Lawyer Needs to Know the Number 384. By John G. McCabe, M.A. and Justin C. Mary Confidence in Sampling: Why Every Lawyer Needs to Know the Number 384 By John G. McCabe, M.A. and Justin C. Mary Both John (john.mccabe.555@gmail.com) and Justin (justin.mary@cgu.edu.) are in Ph.D. programs

More information

ORIENTATION SAN FRANCISCO STOP SMOKING PROGRAM

ORIENTATION SAN FRANCISCO STOP SMOKING PROGRAM ORIENTATION SAN FRANCISCO STOP SMOKING PROGRAM PURPOSE To introduce the program, tell the participants what to expect, and set an overall positive tone for the series. AGENDA Item Time 0.1 Acknowledgement

More information

An Understanding of Role of Heuristic on Investment Decisions

An Understanding of Role of Heuristic on Investment Decisions International Review of Business and Finance ISSN 0976-5891 Volume 9, Number 1 (2017), pp. 57-61 Research India Publications http://www.ripublication.com An Understanding of Role of Heuristic on Investment

More information

HEES for Spanish- Speaking Customers

HEES for Spanish- Speaking Customers Southern California Edison HEES for Spanish- Speaking Customers Study ID: SCE0291.01 Addendum to Study ID SCE 0275.01 September 2010 Prepared for: Caroline Chen, Southern California Edison Prepared by:

More information

Flex case study. Pádraig MacGinty Owner, North West Hearing Clinic Donegal, Ireland

Flex case study. Pádraig MacGinty Owner, North West Hearing Clinic Donegal, Ireland Flex case study Pádraig MacGinty Owner, North West Hearing Clinic Donegal, Ireland Pádraig MacGinty has been in business for 15 years, owning two clinics in North West Ireland. His experience with Flex:trial

More information

T. Kushnir & A. Gopnik (2005 ). Young children infer causal strength from probabilities and interventions. Psychological Science 16 (9):

T. Kushnir & A. Gopnik (2005 ). Young children infer causal strength from probabilities and interventions. Psychological Science 16 (9): Probabilities and Interventions 1 Running Head: PROBABILITIES AND INTERVENTIONS T. Kushnir & A. Gopnik (2005 ). Young children infer causal strength from probabilities and interventions. Psychological

More information

MULTIPLE LINEAR REGRESSION 24.1 INTRODUCTION AND OBJECTIVES OBJECTIVES

MULTIPLE LINEAR REGRESSION 24.1 INTRODUCTION AND OBJECTIVES OBJECTIVES 24 MULTIPLE LINEAR REGRESSION 24.1 INTRODUCTION AND OBJECTIVES In the previous chapter, simple linear regression was used when you have one independent variable and one dependent variable. This chapter

More information

Critical Review Form Clinical Decision Analysis

Critical Review Form Clinical Decision Analysis Critical Review Form Clinical Decision Analysis An Interdisciplinary Initiative to Reduce Radiation Exposure: Evaluation of Appendicitis in a Pediatric Emergency Department with Clinical Assessment Supported

More information

ASSOCIATION FOR CONSUMER RESEARCH

ASSOCIATION FOR CONSUMER RESEARCH ASSOCIATION FOR CONSUMER RESEARCH Labovitz School of Business & Economics, University of Minnesota Duluth, 11 E. Superior Street, Suite 210, Duluth, MN 55802 Safe and Easy Or Risky and Burdensome? Fluency

More information

On the diversity principle and local falsifiability

On the diversity principle and local falsifiability On the diversity principle and local falsifiability Uriel Feige October 22, 2012 1 Introduction This manuscript concerns the methodology of evaluating one particular aspect of TCS (theoretical computer

More information

Comparing Direct and Indirect Measures of Just Rewards: What Have We Learned?

Comparing Direct and Indirect Measures of Just Rewards: What Have We Learned? Comparing Direct and Indirect Measures of Just Rewards: What Have We Learned? BARRY MARKOVSKY University of South Carolina KIMMO ERIKSSON Mälardalen University We appreciate the opportunity to comment

More information

How Does Analysis of Competing Hypotheses (ACH) Improve Intelligence Analysis?

How Does Analysis of Competing Hypotheses (ACH) Improve Intelligence Analysis? How Does Analysis of Competing Hypotheses (ACH) Improve Intelligence Analysis? Richards J. Heuer, Jr. Version 1.2, October 16, 2005 This document is from a collection of works by Richards J. Heuer, Jr.

More information

Response Tendency in a Questionnaire

Response Tendency in a Questionnaire Response Tendency in a Questionnaire without Questions J. van Heerden and Joh. Hoogstraten University of Amsterdam In a replication of an earlier study by Berg and Rapaport (1954), a questionnaire with

More information

Psychological. Influences on Personal Probability. Chapter 17. Copyright 2005 Brooks/Cole, a division of Thomson Learning, Inc.

Psychological. Influences on Personal Probability. Chapter 17. Copyright 2005 Brooks/Cole, a division of Thomson Learning, Inc. Psychological Chapter 17 Influences on Personal Probability Copyright 2005 Brooks/Cole, a division of Thomson Learning, Inc. 17.2 Equivalent Probabilities, Different Decisions Certainty Effect: people

More information

Does momentary accessibility influence metacomprehension judgments? The influence of study judgment lags on accessibility effects

Does momentary accessibility influence metacomprehension judgments? The influence of study judgment lags on accessibility effects Psychonomic Bulletin & Review 26, 13 (1), 6-65 Does momentary accessibility influence metacomprehension judgments? The influence of study judgment lags on accessibility effects JULIE M. C. BAKER and JOHN

More information

b. Associate Professor at UCLA Anderson School of Management

b. Associate Professor at UCLA Anderson School of Management 1 The Benefits of Emergency Reserves: Greater Preference and Persistence for Goals having Slack with a Cost MARISSA A. SHARIF a and SUZANNE B. SHU b a. PhD Candidate at UCLA Anderson School of Management

More information

How rational are humans? Many important implications hinge. Qu a r t e r ly Jo u r n a l of. Vol. 15 N o Au s t r i a n.

How rational are humans? Many important implications hinge. Qu a r t e r ly Jo u r n a l of. Vol. 15 N o Au s t r i a n. The Qu a r t e r ly Jo u r n a l of Vol. 15 N o. 3 370 374 Fall 2012 Au s t r i a n Ec o n o m i c s Book Review Thinking, Fast and Slow Dan i e l Ka h n e m a n Lon d o n: Al l e n La n e, 2011, 499 p

More information

Autonomy as a Positive Value Some Conceptual Prerequisites Niklas Juth Dept. of Philosophy, Göteborg University

Autonomy as a Positive Value Some Conceptual Prerequisites Niklas Juth Dept. of Philosophy, Göteborg University Philosophical Communications, Web Series, No. 28 Dept. of Philosophy, Göteborg University, Sweden ISSN 1652-0459 Autonomy as a Positive Value Some Conceptual Prerequisites Niklas Juth Dept. of Philosophy,

More information

What s in Your Wallet? Psychophysical Biases in the Estimation of Money. Priya Raghubir Mario Capizzani Joydeep Srivastava* November 1, 2016

What s in Your Wallet? Psychophysical Biases in the Estimation of Money. Priya Raghubir Mario Capizzani Joydeep Srivastava* November 1, 2016 What s in Your Wallet? Psychophysical Biases in the Estimation of Money Priya Raghubir Mario Capizzani Joydeep Srivastava* November 1, 2016 *Priya Raghubir is the Dean Abraham L. Gitlow Professor of Business,

More information

Chapter 12. The One- Sample

Chapter 12. The One- Sample Chapter 12 The One- Sample z-test Objective We are going to learn to make decisions about a population parameter based on sample information. Lesson 12.1. Testing a Two- Tailed Hypothesis Example 1: Let's

More information

Does Unconscious Thought Outperform Conscious Thought On Complex Decisions? A Further Examination

Does Unconscious Thought Outperform Conscious Thought On Complex Decisions? A Further Examination Bowling Green State University ScholarWorks@BGSU Psychology Faculty Publications Psychology 4-2009 Does Unconscious Thought Outperform Conscious Thought On Complex Decisions? A Further Examination Scott

More information

THE USE OF MULTIVARIATE ANALYSIS IN DEVELOPMENT THEORY: A CRITIQUE OF THE APPROACH ADOPTED BY ADELMAN AND MORRIS A. C. RAYNER

THE USE OF MULTIVARIATE ANALYSIS IN DEVELOPMENT THEORY: A CRITIQUE OF THE APPROACH ADOPTED BY ADELMAN AND MORRIS A. C. RAYNER THE USE OF MULTIVARIATE ANALYSIS IN DEVELOPMENT THEORY: A CRITIQUE OF THE APPROACH ADOPTED BY ADELMAN AND MORRIS A. C. RAYNER Introduction, 639. Factor analysis, 639. Discriminant analysis, 644. INTRODUCTION

More information

Moralization Through Moral Shock: Exploring Emotional Antecedents to Moral Conviction. Table of Contents

Moralization Through Moral Shock: Exploring Emotional Antecedents to Moral Conviction. Table of Contents Supplemental Materials 1 Supplemental Materials for Wisneski and Skitka Moralization Through Moral Shock: Exploring Emotional Antecedents to Moral Conviction Table of Contents 2 Pilot Studies 2 High Awareness

More information

ASSOCIATION FOR CONSUMER RESEARCH

ASSOCIATION FOR CONSUMER RESEARCH ASSOCIATION FOR CONSUMER RESEARCH Labovitz School of Business & Economics, University of Minnesota Duluth, 11 E. Superior Street, Suite 210, Duluth, MN 55802 Time Pressure and the Compromise and Attraction

More information

Discrimination and Generalization in Pattern Categorization: A Case for Elemental Associative Learning

Discrimination and Generalization in Pattern Categorization: A Case for Elemental Associative Learning Discrimination and Generalization in Pattern Categorization: A Case for Elemental Associative Learning E. J. Livesey (el253@cam.ac.uk) P. J. C. Broadhurst (pjcb3@cam.ac.uk) I. P. L. McLaren (iplm2@cam.ac.uk)

More information

How do People Really Think about Climate Change?

How do People Really Think about Climate Change? How do People Really Think about Climate Change? #LSESunstein Professor Cass Sunstein Robert Walmsley University Professor at Harvard Law School. Former Administrator of the White House Office of Information

More information

Models of Parent-Offspring Conflict Ethology and Behavioral Ecology

Models of Parent-Offspring Conflict Ethology and Behavioral Ecology Models of Parent-Offspring Conflict Ethology and Behavioral Ecology A. In this section we will look the nearly universal conflict that will eventually arise in any species where there is some form of parental

More information

The wicked learning environment of regression toward the mean

The wicked learning environment of regression toward the mean The wicked learning environment of regression toward the mean Working paper December 2016 Robin M. Hogarth 1 & Emre Soyer 2 1 Department of Economics and Business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona 2

More information

Choices and affective reactions to negative life events: An averaging/summation analysis

Choices and affective reactions to negative life events: An averaging/summation analysis Judgment and Decision Making, Vol. 3, No. 5, June 2008, pp. 425 434 Choices and affective reactions to negative life events: An averaging/summation analysis John J. Seta University of North Carolina at

More information

Product Assortment and Individual Decision Processes

Product Assortment and Individual Decision Processes Journal of Personality and Social Psychology Copyright 2003 by the American Psychological Association, Inc. 2003, Vol. 85, No. 1, 151 162 0022-3514/03/$12.00 DOI: 10.1037/0022-3514.85.1.151 Product Assortment

More information

Reliability and Validity checks S-005

Reliability and Validity checks S-005 Reliability and Validity checks S-005 Checking on reliability of the data we collect Compare over time (test-retest) Item analysis Internal consistency Inter-rater agreement Compare over time Test-Retest

More information

Understanding Uncertainty in School League Tables*

Understanding Uncertainty in School League Tables* FISCAL STUDIES, vol. 32, no. 2, pp. 207 224 (2011) 0143-5671 Understanding Uncertainty in School League Tables* GEORGE LECKIE and HARVEY GOLDSTEIN Centre for Multilevel Modelling, University of Bristol

More information

Indecisiveness and response to risk in deciding when to decide

Indecisiveness and response to risk in deciding when to decide Wesleyan University WesScholar Division III Faculty Publications Natural Sciences and Mathematics January 2007 Indecisiveness and response to risk in deciding when to decide Andrea L. Patalano Wesleyan

More information

Math 140 Introductory Statistics

Math 140 Introductory Statistics Math 140 Introductory Statistics Professor Silvia Fernández Sample surveys and experiments Most of what we ve done so far is data exploration ways to uncover, display, and describe patterns in data. Unfortunately,

More information

Understanding Consumers Processing of Online Review Information

Understanding Consumers Processing of Online Review Information Understanding Consumers Processing of Online Review Information Matthew McNeill mmcneil@clemson.edu Nomula Siddarth-Reddy snomula@clemson.edu Dr. Tom T. Baker Clemson University School of Marketing 234

More information

DRAFT (Final) Concept Paper On choosing appropriate estimands and defining sensitivity analyses in confirmatory clinical trials

DRAFT (Final) Concept Paper On choosing appropriate estimands and defining sensitivity analyses in confirmatory clinical trials DRAFT (Final) Concept Paper On choosing appropriate estimands and defining sensitivity analyses in confirmatory clinical trials EFSPI Comments Page General Priority (H/M/L) Comment The concept to develop

More information

When Imagination Hinders Behavior: The Effects of Outcome versus Process-Oriented Thinking. on Decision Difficulty and Performance

When Imagination Hinders Behavior: The Effects of Outcome versus Process-Oriented Thinking. on Decision Difficulty and Performance When Imagination Hinders Behavior: The Effects of Outcome versus Process-Oriented Thinking on Decision Difficulty and Performance DEBORA VIANA THOMPSON REBECCA W. HAMILTON PETIA K. PETROVA Journal of Consumer

More information

PREFERENCE REVERSAL: AN EXPERIMENTAL INVESTIGATION OF ECONOMIC AND PSYCHOLOGICAL HYPOTHESES*

PREFERENCE REVERSAL: AN EXPERIMENTAL INVESTIGATION OF ECONOMIC AND PSYCHOLOGICAL HYPOTHESES* PREFERENCE REVERSAL: AN EXPERIMENTAL INVESTIGATION OF ECONOMIC AND PSYCHOLOGICAL HYPOTHESES* by Robin Cubitt** Alistair Munro** Chris Starmer*** * Research for this paper was funded by the Economic and

More information

Investigating Explanations to Justify Choice

Investigating Explanations to Justify Choice Investigating Explanations to Justify Choice Ingrid Nunes 1,2, Simon Miles 2, Michael Luck 2, and Carlos J.P. de Lucena 1 1 Pontifical Catholic University of Rio de Janeiro - Rio de Janeiro, Brazil {ionunes,lucena}@inf.puc-rio.br

More information

scope insensitivity and the mere token effect

scope insensitivity and the mere token effect Oleg Urminsky and ran kivetz* Decisions often involve trade-offs between a more normative option and a less normative but more tempting one. the authors propose that the intrapersonal conflict that is

More information

Folland et al Chapter 4

Folland et al Chapter 4 Folland et al Chapter 4 Chris Auld Economics 317 January 11, 2011 Chapter 2. We won t discuss, but you should already know: PPF. Supply and demand. Theory of the consumer (indifference curves etc) Theory

More information

It is often implied, and sometimes explicitly asserted, that folk psychology is best

It is often implied, and sometimes explicitly asserted, that folk psychology is best Folk Psychology and Folk Morality: Response to Critics 1 Joshua Knobe Princeton University It is often implied, and sometimes explicitly asserted, that folk psychology is best understood as a kind of predictive

More information

BLUE JAY MANUSCRIPT REVIEW HISTORY REVIEWS (ROUND 1) Editor Decision Letter

BLUE JAY MANUSCRIPT REVIEW HISTORY REVIEWS (ROUND 1) Editor Decision Letter 1 BLUE JAY MANUSCRIPT REVIEW HISTORY REVIEWS (ROUND 1) Editor Decision Letter Thank you for submitting your manuscript to the Journal of Consumer Research. The manuscript has been read by two reviewers

More information

An Investigation of Factors Influencing Causal Attributions in Managerial Decision Making

An Investigation of Factors Influencing Causal Attributions in Managerial Decision Making Marketing Letters 9:3 (1998): 301 312 1998 Kluwer Academic Publishers, Manufactured in The Netherlands An Investigation of Factors Influencing Causal Attributions in Managerial Decision Making SUNDER NARAYANAN

More information

Chapter 5: Research Language. Published Examples of Research Concepts

Chapter 5: Research Language. Published Examples of Research Concepts Chapter 5: Research Language Published Examples of Research Concepts Contents Constructs, Types of Variables, Types of Hypotheses Note Taking and Learning References Constructs, Types of Variables, Types

More information

The Regression-Discontinuity Design

The Regression-Discontinuity Design Page 1 of 10 Home» Design» Quasi-Experimental Design» The Regression-Discontinuity Design The regression-discontinuity design. What a terrible name! In everyday language both parts of the term have connotations

More information

Incorporating quantitative information into a linear ordering" GEORGE R. POTTS Dartmouth College, Hanover, New Hampshire 03755

Incorporating quantitative information into a linear ordering GEORGE R. POTTS Dartmouth College, Hanover, New Hampshire 03755 Memory & Cognition 1974, Vol. 2, No.3, 533 538 Incorporating quantitative information into a linear ordering" GEORGE R. POTTS Dartmouth College, Hanover, New Hampshire 03755 Ss were required to learn linear

More information

10 Intraclass Correlations under the Mixed Factorial Design

10 Intraclass Correlations under the Mixed Factorial Design CHAPTER 1 Intraclass Correlations under the Mixed Factorial Design OBJECTIVE This chapter aims at presenting methods for analyzing intraclass correlation coefficients for reliability studies based on a

More information

Ree M Meertens 1*, Vivian MJ Van de Gaar 2, Maitta Spronken 3 and Nanne K de Vries 1

Ree M Meertens 1*, Vivian MJ Van de Gaar 2, Maitta Spronken 3 and Nanne K de Vries 1 Meertens et al. BMC Medical Informatics and Decision Making 2013, 13:136 RESEARCH ARTICLE Open Access Prevention praised, cure preferred: results of between-subjects experimental studies comparing (monetary)

More information

Evaluation Models STUDIES OF DIAGNOSTIC EFFICIENCY

Evaluation Models STUDIES OF DIAGNOSTIC EFFICIENCY 2. Evaluation Model 2 Evaluation Models To understand the strengths and weaknesses of evaluation, one must keep in mind its fundamental purpose: to inform those who make decisions. The inferences drawn

More information

CHAPTER 3 METHOD AND PROCEDURE

CHAPTER 3 METHOD AND PROCEDURE CHAPTER 3 METHOD AND PROCEDURE Previous chapter namely Review of the Literature was concerned with the review of the research studies conducted in the field of teacher education, with special reference

More information

Do Your Online Friends Make You Pay? A Randomized Field Experiment on Peer Influence in Online Social Networks Online Appendix

Do Your Online Friends Make You Pay? A Randomized Field Experiment on Peer Influence in Online Social Networks Online Appendix Forthcoming in Management Science 2014 Do Your Online Friends Make You Pay? A Randomized Field Experiment on Peer Influence in Online Social Networks Online Appendix Ravi Bapna University of Minnesota,

More information

What are Indexes and Scales

What are Indexes and Scales ISSUES Exam results are on the web No student handbook, will have discussion questions soon Next exam will be easier but want everyone to study hard Biggest problem was question on Research Design Next

More information

Basic Concepts in Research and DATA Analysis

Basic Concepts in Research and DATA Analysis Basic Concepts in Research and DATA Analysis 1 Introduction: A Common Language for Researchers...2 Steps to Follow When Conducting Research...2 The Research Question...3 The Hypothesis...3 Defining the

More information

Reduce Tension by Making the Desired Choice Easier

Reduce Tension by Making the Desired Choice Easier Daniel Kahneman Talk at Social and Behavioral Sciences Meeting at OEOB Reduce Tension by Making the Desired Choice Easier Here is one of the best theoretical ideas that psychology has to offer developed

More information

Incorporating Experimental Research Designs in Business Communication Research

Incorporating Experimental Research Designs in Business Communication Research Incorporating Experimental Research Designs in Business Communication Research Chris Lam, Matt Bauer Illinois Institute of Technology The authors would like to acknowledge Dr. Frank Parker for his help

More information

A Belief-Based Account of Decision under Uncertainty. Craig R. Fox, Amos Tversky

A Belief-Based Account of Decision under Uncertainty. Craig R. Fox, Amos Tversky A Belief-Based Account of Decision under Uncertainty Craig R. Fox, Amos Tversky Outline Problem Definition Decision under Uncertainty (classical Theory) Two-Stage Model Probability Judgment and Support

More information

PEER REVIEW HISTORY ARTICLE DETAILS TITLE (PROVISIONAL)

PEER REVIEW HISTORY ARTICLE DETAILS TITLE (PROVISIONAL) PEER REVIEW HISTORY BMJ Open publishes all reviews undertaken for accepted manuscripts. Reviewers are asked to complete a checklist review form (http://bmjopen.bmj.com/site/about/resources/checklist.pdf)

More information