Estimating the Potential Impact of a Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Excise Tax

Similar documents
CAN TAXES ON CALORICALLY SWEETENED BEVERAGES REDUCE OBESITY?

Sugar-sweetened Beverage Taxes, Consumption and Obesity. Webinar

Exploring How Prices and Advertisements for Soda in Food Stores Influence Adolescents Dietary Behavior

Healthy Drinks Fast Facts

Taxing Sugary Drinks in Canada: Evidence and Challenges. Dr. Tom Warshawski Chair, Childhood Obesity Foundation

Taxes, Advertising and Obesity: Public Policy Implications

Miao Zhen, John Beghin and Helen Jensen Iowa State University CMD Meeting, Banff, Alberta September 28-30,2009

Use of Diversion Ratios in Addressing the Consequences of Tax Policies Associated with Non-alcoholic Beverages

ORIGINAL INVESTIGATION. Impact of Targeted Beverage Taxes on Higher- and Lower-Income Households

The Economics of Fast Food and Soda: Evidence and Policy Implications for Child and Adolescent Obesity

Predicting Impacts of Targeted Beverage Taxes: Research Challenges and Potential Solutions

Sugary Drink Webinar

Taxing Caloric Sweetened Beverages To Curb Obesity

SUGAR. DAVID HAMMOND PhD. Applied Public Health Chair

HEALTH LEVY ON SUGAR- SWEETENED BEVERAGES Rethink Sugary Drink Position Statement

One Cent Per Ounce Excise Tax on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages* Rossan Chen, MD MSc, Matt Symkowick, MD

Do students compensate for school beverage laws? Evidence that removing soda from schools is not enough

City of Minneapolis Healthier Beverage Initiative Talking Points - suggested answers for partners

Tax Sugar-Sweetened Beverages. Janice Macdonald. MEd, RD, FDC Director of Communications Dietitians of Canada

Price, Food Consumption, and Obesity

Obesity Health Alliance. The Soft Drinks Industry Levy Policy Briefing

Carbonated soft drinks, or soda, and. Soda Taxes, Soft Drink Consumption, And Children s Body Mass Index. Web First

Increased city excise tax linked to change in BMI through change in SSB price and consumption. SSB Consumption. SSB Price

Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Tax San Francisco, CA

SOFT DRINK TAXES A Policy Brief

Sugary-Drink Excise Tax West Virginia

Reducing Sugary Beverage Consumption Across the US: A Policy Update for RDs

Prevalence, Trends and Disparities in Beverage Consumption Among Young Children aged 0-24 months from NHANES

Cigarette Consumption: Estimating the Effects of an Excise Cigarette Tax in California

Scientific Report of the 2015 Dietary Guidelines Advisory Committee

Intake of sugar-sweetened beverages and weight gain: a systematic review REVIEW ARTICLE

Agricultural Policies and Obesity: The Linkages Between Farm Commodities and Retail Food Products

DENVER: Sugary Drink Excise Tax

Pricing of Food: can we use this to promote healthy nutrition?

Implications of a Healthier U.S. Food Stamp Program

The potential health effects of taxing sugary drinks in Estonia

Snack Food and Beverage Interventions in Schools

IDF Framework for Action on Sugar

The sugar reduction environment. Professor Julian G. Mercer Rowett Institute

Public Health. obesity reviews. L. M. Powell 1,2, J. F. Chriqui 2, T. Khan 3,R.Wada 2 and F. J. Chaloupka 2,3. Summary.

Which could be made worse by the over-consumption of sugar or calories?

EvidenceSynthesis OVERVIEW

Why the Increase In Obesity

Case Study Report Classification Quantification. Evaluation of Council Directive 92/83/EEC

DRAFT FOR CONSULTATION

The Effects of Taxing Sugar Sweetened Beverages ERASMUS UNIVERSITY ROTTERDAM. Erasmus School of Economics. Departments of Economics

May 2017 How do taxes on sugar-sweetened beverages affect health and health care costs?

Current issues in childhood overweight and obesity: a clinical and public health perspective.

Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Intake among EFNEP Participants An Evaluation Using the National EFNEP Database

Public Health Association of Australia: Policy-at-a-glance Health Levy on Sugar Sweetened Beverage Position Statement

Sugar Reduction: The evidence for action. All Party Parliamentary Food and Health Forum October 2015

Technical Appendix to Working Paper 10-WP 518. Accounting for Product Substitution in the Analysis of Food Taxes Targeting Obesity

GLOBAL PERSPECTIVES: AN OVERVIEW OF THE GLOBAL PROTEIN LANDSCAPE CHRIS SCHMIDT SENIOR CONSUMER HEALTH ANALYST MAY 3-4, 2016

This is a repository copy of How successful will the sugar levy be in improving diet and reducing inequalities in health?.

Improving School Food Environments Through District-Level Policies: Findings from Six California Case Studies. Executive Summary JULY 2006

What is the Current Evidence on Taxes and Subsidies on Food? Structure

IN THE GENERAL ASSEMBLY STATE OF. Competitive School Food and Beverage Act. Be it enacted by the People of the State of, represented in the General

What should I drink? Monica Esquivel ECHO Diabetes Learning Group December 6, 2017

The Public Health and Economic Benefits of Taxing Sugar-Sweetened Beverages

Food prices and food consumption: potential contradictions between health and economic policy

Shifts in purchasing patterns of non-alcoholic, water-based beverages in Australia,

Rethink Your Drink Campaign DRINK WATER WEEK

Thank You to Our Sponsors: Evaluations. Sugary Beverages: Why the Fuss and What You Can Do. Disclosure Statements

Sugary Beverages: Why the Fuss and What You Can Do

A BRIEF OF A BILL ENTITLED THE

Science-Based Recommendations for Front of Package Labeling. Kelly D. Brownell, Ph.D. Yale University

THE UNEQUAL DISTRIBUTION OF BODY MASS INDEX: EXAMINING THE EFFECT OF STATE-LEVEL SOFT DRINK TAXES ON OBESITY INEQUALITY TAE-YOUNG PAK

Learning Zone Express Learning Zone Express

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ALCOHOL CONSUMPTION AND TAX DIFFERENTIALS BETWEEN BEER, WINE AND SPIRITS. Working Paper No. 3200

Percentage of U.S. Children and Adolescents Who Are Overweight*

2018 Global Nutrition

POST-MILLENNIAL BEVERAGE TRENDS AND THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN PRICE AND FOOD/BEVERAGE INTAKES AND PURCHASES IN THE U.S. PRESCHOOLER

Strategies to Reduce Sugar- Sweetened Beverage Consumption: Lessons from New York City

RESOLUTION NO XX

Position Statement. Health levy on sugar-sweetened beverages. Diabetes Australia recommends that the Australian Government introduce a health

Technical consultation on reducing sugar intake in the Eastern Mediterranean Region

CALIFORNIA BILL TEXT. TITLE: Sugar-sweetened beverages: safety warnings TEXT:

Nutrition Guidelines for Foods and Beverages in AHS Facilities

Impact assessment of the Belgian Convention for a Balanced Diet

The Effects of Taxing Sugar-Sweetened Beverages across different Income Groups

SNAP Decisions Health Impact Assessment. Executive Summary

Rethink Your Drink: Efforts to Address Sugary Drinks through Education and Policy Changes

THE HEALTH AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF A TAX ON SUGARY DRINKS IN ALBERTA AMANDA C JONES & DAVID HAMMOND

THE HEALTH AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF A TAX ON SUGARY DRINKS IN CANADA AMANDA C JONES, J LENNERT VEERMAN & DAVID HAMMOND

Councilmember Laurie Capitelli, Vice Mayor Linda Maio, Councilmember Darryl Moore, and Councilmember Lori Droste

Accounting for Product Substitution in the Analysis of Food Taxes Targeting Obesity. Zhen Miao, John C. Beghin, and Helen H.

Accounting for Product Substitution in the Analysis of Food Taxes Targeting Obesity

WHO Draft Guideline: Sugars intake for adults and children. About the NCD Alliance. Summary:

Sugary drink policy 2017 State of Play

Harnessing the Food Environment to make Healthy, the Easy Choice

Consumer Sovereignty and Healthy Eating: Dilemmas for Research and Policy. W Bruce Traill The University of Reading

Public Health Nutrition:

What's Happened to Dairy Product Sales and Why? by Karen Bunch a

Promoting Healthy Beverage Consumption:

BEVERAGES. Risks and opportunities: the science. Sigrid Gibson. Director, Sig- Nurture Ltd. Nutrition Consultants

MILLENNIALS AND ORANGE JUICE CONSUMPTION

Citywide Healthy Snack and Beverage Vending Policy

SMART SNACKS IN SCHOOL. USDA s All Foods Sold in School Nutrition Standards New for Snacks and Beverages

Transcription:

Ebarb 1 Intermediate Economics Amber Ebarb Fall 2015, Elasticity Memo Estimating the Potential Impact of a Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Excise Tax Growing awareness of the link between sugar-sweetened beverages (SSBs) and America s obesity epidemic has led policy-makers to consider government interventions to reduce SSB consumption. A large body of scientific literature links consumption of SSBs to obesity, type 2 diabetes, and many adverse health outcomes. 1, 2, 3 Epidemic obesity levels cost the United States billions in medical care, estimated at $190 billion per year (one-fifth of U.S. national health expenditures). 4 A recent study estimates that SSBs account for 20 percent of the weight gain from 1977 to 2007 in the U.S. population. 5 Moreover, SSBs produce less satiety, leading to increases in total energy intake over the long term. 6 In March of 2015, Rep. Rosa DeLauro introduced the SWEET Act, which would impose a federal excise tax on the sale of any specified sugar-sweetened beverage by the manufacturer, producer, or importer thereof at a rate of one cent per 4.2 grams (one teaspoon) of caloric sweetener. This memo estimates this tax for major categories of SSBs and the potential change in quantity of SSBs consumed per capita based on a range of elasticities of demand. Under a tax (if fully shifted to consumers) of one cent per teaspoon of sugar, individual per capita consumption could decline by 17 percent for non-diet carbonated soft drinks, 13 percent for fruit drinks, 16 percent for sports drinks, and 11 percent for energy drinks, using the mean elasticity of demand for each (Tables 3-6). Annual per capita consumption of the total SSBs analyzed in this memo could drop from 41.4 gallons to 34.6 gallons, a 17 percent reduction. Background on SSB Taxes and the SWEET Act: Recent government interventions, such as in Berkeley, CA and the Navajo Nation, include taxing of SSBs to reduce consumption, curb obesity, and raise government revenue. These and other proposed Pigouvian taxes aim to address a negative externality of SSBs, which is that obesity increases health care costs for taxpayers who are third parties to the transactions between consumers and producers of SSBs. 7 Overweight and obese individuals do not bear the full cost of their increased weight, and a tax on SSBs attempts to modify SSB price to match true social cost. Most of the existing SSB excise tax proposals would impose a per-volume tax, usually a cent

Ebarb 2 per ounce of SSB; but Zhen and colleagues note that a calorie-based SSB tax would be more efficient than an ounce-based tax in achieving an added-sugar reduction target. 8 A tax aimed at curbing obesity should target the specific ingredient of concern (sugar), which varies widely in SSB products. The SWEET Act employs the calorie-based approach, which may be more efficient than the ounce-based tax in reducing added-sugar consumption, but will result in different tax rates per SSB product. Most studies reviewed for this memo estimate the reduction in SSBs consumed based on the onecent per ounce tax, instead of the one-cent per teaspoon of sugar tax. This memo estimates SWEET Act taxes per major type of SSB based on respective average sugar content for each (Table 1). Estimating Change in Quantity due to the SWEET Act: The SWEET Act would impose a tax of one-cent per 4.2 grams of caloric sweetener contained in specified sugar-sweetened beverages. 9 Exceptions include milk, soy, rice, or similar plant-based milk substitute; 100% juice; infant formula; certain medical, nutritional, and electrolyte solutions; and alcohol these beverages are excluded from this analysis. The SWEET Act would be adjusted for inflation in subsequent years and revenues raised from the tax would fund diet-related health research through the Prevention and Public Health Fund. Defining SSB Quantity: Given that the SWEET Act imposes a tax based on sugar content and not SSB volume, this memo first identifies available data for SSB quantities consumed and associated sugar content. Andreyeva and colleagues combine industry beverage volume data with Census population estimates to calculate annual per capita consumption in 2009 of non-diet carbonated soft drinks (CSDs), fruit drinks (excluding 100% juice), sports drinks, energy drinks, as well as ready-to-drink (RTD) teas and coffees (due to inconsistent data on RTD teas and coffees, the two were not included in this memo, although their consumption quantities were relatively low compared to CSDs and the other SSBs). 10 Sugar Content: The U.S. Department of Agriculture, National Nutrient Database provides data for grams of sugar per fluid ounce for many SSBs specified in the SWEET Act. Sugar content within SSB subcategories vary, so sugar content for this memo uses the mean of many products in each group for calculations (Table 1).

Ebarb 3 SSB Prices: Powell and colleagues provide the average price per ounce in 2012 dollars for many SSBs based on data collected from 2010 through 2012 in a national sample where 8th, 10th, and 12th grade public school students live. 11 For this memo, prices were adjusted for inflation to 2015 dollars. Estimated Tax per SSB Category: The estimated tax per ounce of SSB is calculated by dividing the average grams of sugar per ounce of SSB by 4.2 grams to obtain the teaspoons of sugar per ounce and then multiplying that result by $.01, the SWEET Act tax. Table 1: Beverage (A) Annual per capita consumption* (gallons) 12 (B) Grams of Sugar per Oz 13 (C) Teaspoons of Sugar (4.2 g) per Oz = (B)/4.2 (D) Original Price per Oz ($) 14 (E) Tax per Oz = $.01 x (C) (F) Tax = (E)/(D) CSDs (not diet) 31.2 3.05 0.73 $0.051 $0.007 14.2% Fruit drinks 3 (range: 3.7, (except 100% 5.2 3.3, 2.38, 2.5) fruit juice) 0.71 $0.077 $0.007 9.3% Sports drinks 1.7 (range: 1.6, 3.8 1.8) 0.40 $0.062 $0.004 6.5% Energy drinks 3.4 (range: 3.2, 1.2 3.14, 3.8, 3.5) 0.81 $0.214 $0.008 3.8% *Assuming per capita consumption has not changed from 2009. Elasticities of Demand: Effectively addressing obesity, the SSB externality, depends on how much a price change reduces SSBs consumed, which partly depends on elasticity of demand. Powell and colleagues offer a systematic review of U.S. studies on the price elasticity of demand for SSBs, including subcategories for non-diet CSDs (mean E d = -1.21), fruit drinks (mean E d = -1.41), and sports drinks (mean E d = -2.44). 15 Okrent and colleagues estimate the elasticity of demand for energy drinks (mean E d = -2.84). 16 Tables 3 through 6 list the high and low elasticities of each. Price elasticities for SSB subcategories allow estimates for quantities consumed after the implementation of the SWEET Act tax. Given that a tax on sugar content would impact regular sodas and beverages but not diet versions, price elasticities of demand for SSBs excluding diet versions are used. A tax on higher sugar content beverages would potentially reduce SSB consumption more than a tax on both SSB and non-ssb drinks because, under a calorie-based tax, consumers could substitute to diet versions of drinks. 17 Tax Incidence: The effectiveness of an SSB excise tax on reducing consumption also depends partly on the pass-through rate of the tax to consumers. This memo estimates the quantity of SSBs

Ebarb 4 consumed with three tax incidence scenarios where the SSB tax shifts fully to consumers, under shifts (0.5), and over shifts (1.5). Most literature reviewed for this memo assumes that an SSB tax is passed on one for one to consumers. The statutory burden of the SWEET Act tax would be imposed on producers: however, the extent to which the tax is passed through to consumers in higher prices, the economic tax incidence, depends on the relative elasticities of supply and demand in perfect competition. A working paper on Berkeley s SSB tax incidence estimates that retail prices rose by less than half of the amount of the tax, contrary to other empirical research findings that SSB excise taxes tend to be fully shifted, if not over shifted, to consumers, such as in Mexico, France, and Denmark. 18 Taxes implemented at sub-levels of government, such as in Berkeley, CA, may be evaded through cross-border shopping outside of the taxed jurisdiction, whereas a national level SSB excise tax would be harder to avoid. 19 Given the ease in cross-border shopping with a city-level tax, some retailers may under shift the tax to consumers to avoid losing customers, resulting in less price change and SSB reduction than at the national level. Falbe notes that in monopolistic or oligopolistic markets, taxes may be overshifted; as other new jurisdictions impose SSB taxes, empirically studying prices and pass-through rates will help inform the effectiveness of SSB taxes. 20 Given the range of pass-through rates of SSB taxes reviewed in the literature, this memo estimates SSB consumption with the tax fully shifted to consumers, shifted 50 percent, and shifted 150 percent. Impact on SSB Consumption: Using the data and assumptions above, Tables 2 through 6 display estimated annual per capita consumption in gallons of non-diet carbonated soft drinks, fruit drinks, sports drinks, and energy drinks with a one-cent tax on 4.2 grams of sugar. Quantities are estimated for a range of elasticities of demand and for the three scenarios of tax incidence mentioned above. Before the tax, Americans consumed 41.4 gallons annually per capita of the SSBs named above (31.2 gallons of CSDs, 5.2 gallons of fruit drinks, 3.8 gallons of sports drinks, 1.2 gallons of energy drinks). After the tax, using the mean elasticities of demand for each SSB type, and assuming the tax is fully shifted to consumers, the overall quantity of SSBs consumed would drop to 34.6 gallons per capita annually, a 17 percent reduction. Using the high demand elasticity, SSB consumption would drop by 29

Ebarb 5 percent to 29 gallons; using the low estimate of elasticity, SSB consumption would decline to 37.5 gallons, a 10 percent reduction. Table 2 shows the total estimated quantity consumed of the four SSBs analyzed under the SWEET Act tax for the three elasticities of demand and the three different incidences of taxation. (Tables 3 through 6 show the detailed price, tax, and new quantities for the four SSB groups.) Table 2: Total SSBs Fully Shifted Tax Under Shifted Tax (0.5) Over Shifted Tax (1.5) Q o = 41.4 gal /person Q n % Reduction Q n % Reduction Q n % Reduction Mean E d 34.6 17% 38.0 8% 31.2 25% High E d 29.3 29% 35.3 15% 23.2 44% Low E d 37.5 10% 39.5 5% 35.6 14% Conclusion: A 17 percent reduction would represent a meaningful decline in SSB consumption; yet the full impact on obesity would depend on a number of other factors not examined in this memo, such as effects of an SSB tax on other beverages and foods. Finkelstein and colleagues examine substitutions and complementarity between SSBs and some food categories, including cookies and ice cream. 21 Their study finds that under an SSB tax, substitution to other beverages was minimal except for fruit juice; this is a concern with the SWEET Act, which exempts 100% fruit juice from the tax. Finkelstein, however, finds no substitution to sugary foods, and actually finds a decrease in ice cream and salty snacks, which both happen to be complements to SSBs. 22 The eventual impact of the SWEET Act ranges from SSB consumption declining by 5 percent to 44 percent in this memo, depending on the elasticities of demand and the extent of tax pass-through. Recent media articles on nationally imposed SSB taxes report that the taxes are mostly passed on to consumers, which renders the lowest estimates in this memo less likely. 23 Opponents to SSB taxes point out the regressive nature of such taxes; proponents point out, however, the regressivity of negative health outcomes, which hurt low-income more than higher income groups. In fact, within the very group in Mexico affected most by diabetes and obesity, low income households, SSB consumption fell by 17 percent. 24 Many other factors must be analyzed to understand the larger impact of the SWEET Act, including: if SSB reduction would actually reduce obesity, if diabetes incidence would decline, how much medical care costs would shrink, and how much tax revenue would be generated. The impact on price and quantity, however, is an essential first step in analyzing the larger impact of the SWEET Act tax.

Ebarb 6 Tables and Figures The tables below display estimated annual per capita consumption, in gallons, of various sugar-sweetened beverages with a 1-cent tax on 4.2 grams of sugar. Quantities are estimated for a range of elasticities of demand for carbonated soft drinks, fruit drinks, sports drinks, and energy drinks. Quantities are also estimated for three scenarios of tax incidence: one where the tax is fully shifted to consumers, second where the tax is under-shifted, and a third where the tax is over-shifted to consumers. Calculation used for table: Qn Qo E d = % Q = Qo For example: E % P Pn Po d = -1.21 = Po Qn 31.2 31.2 0.0583 0.051 0.051 Q n = 31.2 + 31.2( 1.21 x 0.142) = 25.8 Table 3: Carbonated Soft Drinks (CSDs) in Gallons (128 oz = 1 gal) Q o = 31.2 gal/person annually P o = $0.051/oz Estimated Price (P n ) per oz and Quantity (Q n ), gal per capita Tax Shifted to Tax Undershifted: Tax Overshifted: Consumers: P P o + tax o +.5(tax) P o + 1.5(tax).051+.01*(4.2 g of sugar/oz).051*(1+0.5*0.142).051(1+1.5*.142) tax = 14.2% Range of Elasticity of Demand P n = $0.0583 P n = $0.05465 P n = $0.06195 Mean -1.21 25.8 28.5 23.1 High -2.26 21.1 26.2 16.1 Low -0.71 28.0 29.6 26.4 Range of Elasticity of Demand % Change in Quantity = (Q n Q o )/Q o Mean -1.21-17% -9% -26% High -2.26-32% -16% -49% Low -0.71-10% -5% -15% Figure 1: Change in Quantity and Price for CSDs E d = -1.21; tax is shifted 50% to consumers Price ($/gallon) S2 Tax S1 P 2 = $6.99/gal P 1 = $6.53/gal D1 28.5 = Q 2 Q 1 = 31.2gal Quantity of CSD (gallons per capita)

Ebarb 7 Table 4: Fruit Drinks Q o = 5.2 gal/person annually P o = $0.077/oz Estimated Price (P n ) per oz and Quantity (Q n ), gal per capita Fully Shifted Tax Undershifted: Tax Overshifted: to Consumers: P P o + tax o +.5(tax) P o + 1.5(tax).077+.01*(4.2 g of sugar/oz).077*(1+0.5*.093).077(1+1.5*.093) tax = 9.3% Range of Elasticity of Demand P n = $0.0841 P n = $0.0806 P n = $0.0877 Mean -1.41 4.5 4.9 4.2 High -1.91 4.3 4.7 3.8 Low -0.69 4.9 5.0 4.7 Range of Elasticity of Demand % Change in Quantity = (Q n Q o )/Q o Mean -1.41-13% -7% -20% High -1.91-18% -9% -27% Low -0.69-6% -3% -10% Table 5: Sports Drinks Q o = 3.8 gal/person annually P o = $0.062/oz Estimated Price (P n ) per oz and Quantity (Q n ), gal per capita Fully Shifted Tax Tax Overshifted: to Consumers: Undershifted: P P o + tax P o +.5(tax) o + 1.5(tax).062+.01*(4.2 g of sugar/oz).062*(1+0.5*.065).062(1+1.5*.065) tax = 6.5% Range of Elasticity of Demand P n = $0.0660 P n = $0.0640 P n = $0.0681 Mean -2.44 3.2 3.5 2.9 High -3.87 2.8 3.3 2.4 Low -1.01 3.5 3.7 3.4 Range of Elasticity of Demand % Change in Quantity = (Q n Q o )/Q o Mean -2.44-16% -8% -24% High -3.87-25% -13% -38% Low -1.01-7% -3% -10% Table 6: Energy Drinks Q o = 1.2 gal/person annually P o = $0.214/oz Estimated Price (P n ) per oz and Quantity (Q n ), gal per capita Fully Shifted to Tax Undershifted: Tax Overshifted: Consumers: P P o + tax o +.5(tax) P o + 1.5(tax).214+.01*(4.2 g of sugar/oz) 0.214*(1+0.5*.038).0214(1+.1.5*.038) tax = 3.8% Range of Elasticity of Demand P n = $0.2221 P n = $0.2181 P n = $0.2262 Mean -2.84 1.07 1.14 1.01 High -3.46 1.04 1.12 0.96 Low -2.22 1.10 1.15 1.05 Range of Elasticity of Demand % Change in Quantity = (Q n Q o )/Q o Mean -2.84-11% -5% -16% High -3.46-13% -7% -20% Low -2.22-8% -4% -13%

Ebarb 8 Notes 1. Lenny R. Vartanian et al., Effects of soft drink consumption on nutrition and health: a systematic review and meta-analysis, American Journal of Public Health. 97, no. 4 (2007): 667-675. 2. Adam M. Bernstein et al., Soda consumption and the risk of stroke in men and women. American Journal of Clinical Nutrition 95 (2012): 1190-1199. 3. Liwei Chen et al., Reducing consumption of sugar- sweetened beverages is associated with reduced blood pressure: A prospective study among United States adults. Circulation 121 (2011): 2398-2406. 4. John Cawley and Chad Meyerhoefer, The medical care costs of obesity: An instrumental variables approach, Journal of Health Economics 31 (2012): 219-230. 5. Gail Woodward-Lopez et al., To what extent have sweetened beverages contributed to the obesity epidemic? Public Health Nutrition 14, no. 3 (2011): 499-509. 6. An Pana and Frank B. Hu, Effects of carbohydrates on satiety: differences between liquid and solid food, Current Opinion in Clinical Nutrition and Metabolic Care. 14, no. 4 (2011): 385-390. 7. Robin A. McKinnon, A Rationale for Policy Intervention in Reducing Obesity, American Medical Association Journal of Ethics. 12, no. 4 (2010): 309-315. 8. Chen Zhen et al., By Ounce or by Calorie: The Differential Effects of Alternative Sugar- Sweetened Beverage Tax Strategies, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 96/4 (2014): 1070 1083; doi: 10.1093/ajae/aau052. Accessed November 26, 2015 9. Sugar-Sweetened Beverages Tax Act of 2015, HR 1687, 114th Cong., 1st sess. (2015). 10. Tatiana Andreyeva et al., Estimating the potential of taxes on sugar-sweetened beverages to reduce consumption and generate revenue, Preventive Medicine 52 (2011): 413 416. 11. Lisa M. Powell et al., Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Prices: Estimates from a National Sample of Food Outlets, Chicago, IL: Bridging the Gap Program, Health Policy Center, Institute for Health Research 12. Andreyeva et al, Estimating the potential of taxes on sugar-sweetened beverages to reduce consumption and generate revenue, 415. 13. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Research Service. National Nutrient Database, Basic Report, grams of sugar per 1 fl. oz. 14. Powell et al., Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Prices: Estimates from a National Sample of Food Outlets, 2012 price data adjusted for inflation to 2015 real dollars. 15. Lisa M. Powell et al., Assessing the Potential Effectiveness of Food and Beverage Taxes and Subsidies for Improving Public Health: A Systematic Review of Prices, Demand and Body Weight Outcomes. Obesity Review 14, no. 2 (2013): 110 128. doi:10.1111/obr.12002.

Ebarb 9 16. Abigail M. Okrent and Joanna P. MacEwan, The Effects of Prices, Advertising, Expenditures, and Demographics on Demand for Nonalcoholic Beverages, Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 43, no. 1 (2014): 31 52. 17. Andreyeva, Estimating the potential of taxes on sugar-sweetened beverages to reduce consumption and generate revenue. 414. 18. John Cawley and David Frisvold. The Incidence of Taxes on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages: The Case of Berkeley, California. NBER Working Paper No. 21465 (2015). 19. Ibid., 23. 20. Jennifer Falbe et al., Higher Retail Prices of Sugar-Sweetened Beverages 3 Months After Implementation of an Excise Tax in Berkeley, California, American Journal of Public Health, 105, No. 11 (November 2015): 2194 2201. 21. Eric A. Finkelstein et al., Implications of a sugar-sweetened beverage (SSB) tax when substitutions to non-beverage items are considered, Journal of Health Economics 32 (2013): 219 239. 22. Ibid., 223. 23. Stopping slurping: Taxes on fizzy drinks seem to work as intended, The Economist, November 28, 2015. 24. Ibid.

Ebarb 10 Bibliography Andreyeva, Tatiana, Frank J. Chaloupka, Kelly D. Brownell. Estimating the potential of taxes on sugarsweetened beverages to reduce consumption and generate revenue. Preventive Medicine 52 (2011): 413 416. Bernstein, Adam M., Lawrence de Koning, Alan J. Flint, Kathryn M. Rexrode, and Walter C. Willett. Soda consumption and the risk of stroke in men and women. Am J Clin Nutr. 95 (2012): 1190-1199. Cawley, John and Chad Meyerhoefer. The medical care costs of obesity: An instrumental variables approach. Journal of Health Economics 31 (2012): 219-230. Chen, Liwei, Benjamin Caballero, Diane C. Mitchell, Catherine Loria, Pao-Hwa Lin, Catherine M. Champagne, Patricia J. Elmer, Jamy D. Ard, Bryan C. Batch, Cheryl A.M. Anderson, Lawrence J. Appel, Reducing consumption of sugar- sweetened beverages is associated with reduced blood pressure: A prospective study among United States adults. Circulation 121 (2011): 2398-2406. Falbe, Jennifer, Nadia Rojas, Anna H. Grummon, and Kristine A. Madsen. Higher Retail Prices of Sugar-Sweetened Beverages 3 Months After Implementation of an Excise Tax in Berkeley, California. American Journal of Public Health, 105, No. 11 (November 2015): 2194 2201. Friedman, Roberta R. and Kelly D. Brownell. Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Taxes: an Updated Policy Brief. Yale Rudd Center for Food Policy and Obesity (2012). McKinnon, Robin A. A Rationale for Policy Intervention in Reducing Obesity. American Medical Association Journal of Ethics. 12, no. 4 (2010): 309-315. Okrent, Abigail M., and Joanna P. MacEwan, The Effects of Prices, Advertising, Expenditures, and Demographics on Demand for Nonalcoholic Beverages, Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 43, no. 1 (2014): 31 52. Pana, An and Frank B. Hu. Effects of carbohydrates on satiety: differences between liquid and solid food. Current Opinion in Clinical Nutrition and Metabolic Care. 14, no. 4 (2011): 385-390. Powell, Lisa M., Jamie F. Chriqui, Tamkeen Khan, Roy Wada, Frank J. Chaloupka. Assessing the Potential Effectiveness of Food and Beverage Taxes and Subsidies for Improving Public Health: A Systematic Review of Prices, Demand and Body Weight Outcomes. Obesity Review 14, no. 2 (2013): 110 128. doi:10.1111/obr.12002. Powell, Lisa M., Zeynep Isgor, Leah Rimkus, and Frank J. Chaloupka. Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Prices: Estimates from a National Sample of Food Outlets. Chicago, IL: Bridging the Gap Program, Health Policy Center, Institute for Health Research Stopping slurping: Taxes on fizzy drinks seem to work as intended. The Economist. November 28, 2015. Sugar-Sweetened Beverages Tax Act of 2015, HR 1687, 114th Cong., 1st sess. (2015). U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Research Service. National Nutrient Database, Basic Report, grams of sugar per 1 fl. oz.

Ebarb 11 Vartanian, Lenny R., Marlene B. Schwartz, and Kelly D. Brownell. Effects of soft drink consumption on nutrition and health: a systematic review and meta-analysis. American Journal of Public Health 97, no. 4 (2007): 667-675. Woodward-Lopez, Gail, Janice Kao, and Lorrene Ritchie. To what extent have sweetened beverages contributed to the obesity epidemic? Public Health Nutrition 14, no. 3 (2011): 499-509. Zhen, Chen, Ian F. Brissette, and Ryan R. Ruff. By Ounce or by Calorie: The Differential Effects of Alternative Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Tax Strategies. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 96 no. 4 (2014): 1070 1083; doi: 10.1093/ajae/aau052. Accessed November 26, 2015