Contributions and Beliefs in Liner Public Goods Experiment: Difference between Partners and Strangers Design

Similar documents
Partners versus Strangers: Random Rematching in Public Goods Experiments

Revisiting Kindness and Confusion in Public Goods Experiments

Cooperation and Collective Action

Koji Kotani International University of Japan. Abstract

Group Composition and Cooperation

Theoretical Explanations of Treatment Effects in Voluntary Contributions Experiments

DIFFERENCES IN THE ECONOMIC DECISIONS OF MEN AND WOMEN: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE*

Conditional Cooperation in Network Public Goods Experiments

Private vs. Public Strategies in a Voluntary Contributions Mechanism

Leadership with Individual Rewards and Punishments

The Game Prisoners Really Play: Preference Elicitation and the Impact of Communication

Contributions to public goods are often found to be conditional on the willingness of others to

Kiel Institute for the World Economy Duesternbrooker Weg Kiel, Germany

Inequity and Risk Aversion. in Sequential Public Good Games

ExpEc I. Preliminaries

Does Strategic Play Explain the Decay in Contributions in a Public Goods Game? Experimental Evidence

Altruism and Voluntary Provision of Public Goods. Leanne Ma, Katerina Sherstyuk, Malcolm Dowling and Oliver Hill ab

Cooperation and Public Goods Provision

The Voluntary Provision of a Public Good with Binding Multi-Round Commitments

Cooperation among behaviorally heterogeneous players in social dilemma with stay or leave decisions

Voluntary Participation and Spite in Public Good Provision Experiments: An International Comparison

Heterogeneous social preferences and the dynamics of free riding in public goods

Appendix: Instructions for Treatment Index B (Human Opponents, With Recommendations)

When in Rome: Conformity and the Provision of Public Goods. Jeffrey Carpenter. April, 2002 MIDDLEBURY COLLEGE ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER NO.

AN EXPERIMENTAL ANALYSIS OF CONDITIONAL COOPERATION* Rachel Croson, Enrique Fatas and Tibor Neugebauer**

Conditional Cooperation in Network Public Goods Experiments

Public Goods Provision and Sanctioning. in Privileged Groups

Fairness and Reciprocity in the Hawk-Dove game

Affective Social Ties without the Need to Belong?

Friendship in a Public Good Experiment

THE ROLE OF EXPECTATIONS IN THE PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS UNDER THE INFLUENCE OF SOCIAL IDENTITY

Strong Reciprocity and Human Sociality

Today s lecture. A thought experiment. Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness. Overview readings: Fehr and Fischbacher (2002) Sobel (2005)

Tilburg University. Publication date: Link to publication

CeDEx Discussion Paper Series ISSN

JENA ECONOMIC RESEARCH PAPERS

Charitable Giving in the Laboratory: Advantages of the Piecewise Linear Public Goods Game

A Note On the Design of Experiments Involving Public Goods

Stylized Facts and Identification in Public Goods Experiments: The Confusion Confound

ULTIMATUM GAME. An Empirical Evidence. Presented By: SHAHID RAZZAQUE

VOLKSWIRTSCHAFTLICHE ABTEILUNG. Reputations and Fairness in Bargaining Experimental Evidence from a Repeated Ultimatum Game with Fixed Opponents

Social Preferences of Young Adults in Japan: The Roles of Age and Gender

Playing with the Good Guys: A Public Good Game with Endogenous Group Formation

Jakub Steiner The University of Edinburgh. Abstract

Journal of Public Economics

Identifying Social Norms Using Coordination Games: Spectators vs. Stakeholders. CeDEx Discussion Paper Series ISSN

Revisiting Strategic versus Non-Strategic Cooperation

Collective action as a social exchange

A cash effect in ultimatum game experiments

Planning ahead: Eliciting intentions and beliefs in a public goods game

Trust and Testosterone: A Contribution to Neurosociology

Trust and Cooperation: An experimental study*

Conditional Cooperation and Voluntary Contributions to Public Goods

GROUP DECISION MAKING IN RISKY ENVIRONMENT ANALYSIS OF GENDER BIAS

Author's personal copy

Communication, Advice and Beliefs in an Experimental Public Goods Game

Gender and Culture: International Experimental Evidence from Trust Games

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION

Unaffected Strangers Affect Contributions

VOLUNTARY ASSOCIATION IN PUBLIC GOODS EXPERIMENTS: RECIPROCITY, MIMICRY AND EFFICIENCY*

Eliciting Beliefs by Paying in Chance

Using Experimental Methods to Understand Why and How We Give to Charity By Lise Vesterlund

Cooperation in Prisoner s Dilemma Game: Influence of Social Relations

Altruistic Behavior: Lessons from Neuroeconomics. Kei Yoshida Postdoctoral Research Fellow University of Tokyo Center for Philosophy (UTCP)

Women and Men are Different but Equal: Observations of Learning Behavior in Auctions

Which determines Dictating the Risk, risk preference or social image? Experimental evidence-

UC Merced Proceedings of the Annual Meeting of the Cognitive Science Society

Gender Differences in Giving in the Dictator Game: The Role of Reluctant Altruism

Gender and preferences for redistribution in a dynamic production environment

Social framing and cooperation: The roles and interaction of preferences and beliefs

Social Learning and Norms in a Public Goods Experiment with Intergenerational

Loopholes Undermine Donation: An Experiment Motivated by an Organ Donation Priority Loophole in Israel

Area Conferences 2012

Destructive behavior in a Fragile Public Good game

Revisiting strategic versus non-strategic cooperation

The Effect of Rewards and Sanctions in Provision of Public Goods

Endowment Effects and Contribution Strategies in Public Good Experiments

Revisiting strategic versus non-strategic cooperation

Veronika Grimm, Friederike Mengel. Let me sleep on it: Delay reduces rejection rates in Ultimatum Games RM/10/017

Giving To Ingrates?*

Transparency and cooperation in repeated dilemma games: a meta study

University of Zurich. The social side of Homo economicus. Zurich Open Repository and Archive. Rankin, D J. Year: 2011

Sequential Decision and Strategy Vector Methods in Ultimatum Bargaining: Evidence on the Strength of Other- Regarding Behavior

A PRIZE TO GIVE FOR: AN EXPERIMENT ON PUBLIC GOOD FUNDING MECHANISMS*

CeDEx Discussion Paper Series ISSN

Cooperation in Risky Environments: Decisions from Experience in a Stochastic Social Dilemma

Supporting Information

Beauty, Gender and Stereotypes: Evidence from Laboratory Experiments

Social Comparisons and Pro-social Behavior: Testing Conditional Cooperation in a Field Experiment

and potential remedies for inefficiencies. Economists conducted experiments as early as the

Irrationality in Game Theory

Heinrich H. Naxa, Ryan O. Murphya, Kurt A. Ackermann Interactive preferences

Naming and shaming of individuals and teams in a public goods experiment Astrid Dannenberg (University of Kassel)

Using Cognitive Dissonance to Manipulate Social Preferences

Designing agri-environmental contracts: can collective conditionality improve participation?

Homo economicus is dead! How do we know how the mind works? How the mind works

Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness

Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game

Transcription:

Working Paper

Contributions and Beliefs in Liner Public Goods Experiment: Difference between Partners and Strangers Design Tsuyoshi Nihonsugi 1, 2 1 Research Fellow of the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science 2 Graduate School of Economics, Waseda University Correspondence: Tsuyoshi Nihonsugi Waseda University Graduate School of Economics 1-6-1, Nishiwaseda, Shinjuku-ku, Tokyo, 169-8050, Japan E-mail: t.nihonsugi@gmail.com 1

Abstract Our aim is to investigate why a difference in contributions was observed between Strangers and Partners design in linear public goods games. We focus on conditional cooperation and investigate how influential the difference of belief is in the contributions in Strangers and Partners design. Additionally, we try to clarify how much of the contribution is motivated by conditional cooperation. We found that 79.7% and 39.3% of the total contribution in the Partners design and the Strangers design, respectively, are motivated by conditional cooperation. Moreover, the difference in contributions between Strangers and Partners is not fully explained by only a difference of belief. Keywords: conditional cooperation, public good, partners, strangers, experiment JEL classification: C72, C91, H41 2

1. Introduction Many previous studies of linear public goods experiments have compared two matching designs: the Strangers design, which is a repeated single-shot design, and the Partners design, which is a repeated game. Results have shown that the contributions in each design were significantly different (for a survey, see Andreoni and Croson, 2008). However, the differences in contributions that have been observed between Strangers and Partners remain poorly understood. Croson (2007) conducted linear public goods experiments with a Partners design. In this experiment, subjects had to decide how much of their endowment to contribute to the public good and had to estimate the other group members mean contributions (we called this belief). Croson found that there was a significant positive relationship between belief and contribution, using random-effects regression. Therefore, she mentioned that this result strongly supports the idea that contributions stem from conditional cooperation (reciprocity theory). Fischbacher and Gächter (2010) conducted a linear public goods experiment using a Strangers design. Their design also required subjects to estimate the belief, and they observed the same result as Croson (2007). Taken together, the results from both Croson (2007) and Fischbacher and Gächter (2010) show that conditional cooperation is one important explanation of the voluntary contributions, regardless of the matching design. Hence, one possible reason for the difference in contributions between Partners and Strangers is the difference in expectations concerning group members contributions. Therefore, we focus on conditional cooperation and investigate if the differences in contributions between the Strangers and Partners designs could be explained by the differences in belief. Additionally, we try to clarify how much of the contribution is due to conditional cooperation. We conducted a linear public goods experiment with the following three features: (1) We asked the subjects to estimate other members contributions. This method is almost same as the methods used by Croson (2007) and Fischbacher and Gächter (2010). (2) A group member consisted of two subjects, because one subject could easily estimate the other subject s contribution. (3) We provided subjects a payoff table that had complete payoff information, so that they could confirm all their strategies and payoffs easily and not make mistakes in calculating their payoff. Yamakawa et al. (2009) conducted the linear public goods experiment using a payoff table identical to our payoff table, and they observed that any resulting confusion and errors occurred for just 2.0% of all contributions. These three features allowed us to analyze the relation between contributions and beliefs without confusion or other errors. 3

Three findings emerged from our data. First, the contribution and belief in the Partners design were higher than those in the Strangers design. Second, there was a positive correlation between contribution and belief in both the Strangers and Partners designs. Third, 79.7% of contributions in the Partners design were motivated by conditional cooperation. On the other hand, only 39.3% of contributions in the Strangers design were motivated by conditional cooperation. Furthermore, we found that the differences in contributions between the Strangers and Partners designs could not be fully explained merely by the differences in belief. The current study proceeds as follows: Section 2 presents the experimental design. Section 3 presents the analysis and results, and section 4 discusses and draws conclusions about the results. 2. Experimental Design We conducted the experiments in October 2010 at the Economics Department Computer Laboratory of Osaka University in Japan. Our subjects were 40 Osaka university students from various disciplines. 2.1 The Voluntary Contribution Mechanism and Treatment There were two subjects, a and b, and subject i (= a, b) had w i points of initial endowment. Both subjects faced a decision of splitting w i between their own consumption of the private good (x i ) and a contribution to the public good (y i ). The level of the public good each subject received from the contribution was y = 2 +w y, where w y was the initial j=1 y j level of the public good. Therefore, each subject s decision problem was to maximize the payoff π i (x i, y), subject to the constraint x i + y i = w i. We set 0.7 as a marginal per capita return on the voluntary contribution. In addition, we set w i = 24, w y = 3. We assumed that all subjects had the same linear payoff function as follows: 2 π i = 100 24 y i + 0.7 j=1 y j + 3 (1) From (1) it is obvious that a rational and selfish individual would have an incentive to contribute nothing, whereas full contributions would be socially optimal. Our experiment included two experimental treatments: the Strangers treatment (Strangers), in which subjects met only once, and the Partners treatment (Partners), in which the group composition remained throughout the experiment. 4

2.2 Procedures Twenty different subjects participated in each treatment. In both treatments, at the beginning of the experiment, subjects were provided with a record sheet, a payoff table for practice, a payoff table for the actual task, instructions, and a summary sheet of the experimental procedures 1. After reading the instructions, subjects were given five minutes to ask questions. After that, subjects were tested to confirm that they understood the rules and the way they should read their payoff table 2. Our subjects answered 11 control questions, and the number of mean correct answers was 10.65 (standard deviation is 0.6) in Strangers and 10.75 (standard deviation is 0.4) in Partners. After administering the control questions, we corrected the subjects tests and then publicly explained the correct answers. We gave the subjects another five minutes to ask us about the instructions and to examine the payoff table for the actual task. On the basis of these procedures and the subjects test scores, we are certain that all subjects completely understood the rules of the game and were able to readily calculate their payoffs. After that, the subjects were randomly and anonymously allocated to groups of two, and these groups played a linear public goods game for 15 periods. Each subject had to decide how many of 24 points to contribute to the public good and estimate the other group member s contributions on their computer screen. All subjects simultaneously made these decisions. After each period, subjects were informed of the other member s actual contributions and own payoff in that period. After the experiment, we selected an integer number from one to 15 by lottery from a box, and we paid subjects additional money amounting to $6.25 ($1 = 80 yen) if the subjects had estimated correctly during the selected number period 3. Thus, subjects total earnings depended on the outcome from the public goods game for 15 periods and the additional money. After the lottery, all subjects answered the post-experiment questionnaire. We used a z-tree (Fischbacher, 2007) to conduct the experiment. Each treatment required approximately 1.6 hours to complete. The mean earnings per subject were $27.50. 3. Results 3.1 Mean Contributions and Beliefs 1 Experimental instructions and other materials are available upon request from the corresponding author. 2 We provided with a payoff table for practice, and subjects used this payoff table in answering the control questions. 3 This payment scheme followed proper scoring rules (Brier, 1950). Under this scheme, each subject has a single-peaked expected utility function and truthful revelation of her belief is the unique dominant strategy. 5

Fig. 1 shows the mean contributions to the public good and the mean belief about the other member s contributions in each of the two treatments over 15 periods. The mean contribution across 15 periods from Partners is significantly higher than that from Strangers, and similarly for mean belief (Wilcoxon rank sum test, p < 0.01). This result for contribution is consistent with those from a number of previous studies (e.g., Croson, 1996; Keser and van Winden, 2000; Sonnemans et al., 1999). However, we interpret this as the first piece of evidence that there is a difference between Strangers and Partners for belief. Mean Contribution 24 20 16 12 8 4 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 101112131415 Period Mean Belief 24 20 16 12 8 4 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 101112131415 Period Mean Contribution in Partners Mean contribution in Strangers Mean Belief in Partners Mean belief in Strangers Fig. 1. Mean contribution and belief over time in both the Partners and the Strangers. 3.2 The Relation between Contribution and Belief In this sub-section, we investigate the relation between contribution and belief using all the decision data. We use the random-effect regression as follows: CONTRIBUTION it = β 0 + β 1 PERIOD t + β 2 BELIEF it + α i where CONTRIBUTION it is i s contribution to the public good in period t, BELIEF it is the individual s belief of what the other member will contribute in this same period, and α i is an individual indicator variable (i.e., a random effect). The results of the estimation are in Table 1. As can be seen in Table 1, the coefficients of BELIEF are positive and significant in both treatments. This result suggests that conditional cooperation drives subjects to contribute to the public good in both treatments. These results are consistent with those of both Croson (2007) and Fischbacher and Gächter (2010). Since the coefficient of the Partners is bigger than that of the Strangers, conditional cooperation influence is stronger in the Partners than in the Strangers (t-test, p < 0.05). 6

Table 1. Random Effect Regression Results for Contributions Partners Strangers Period -0.188-0.1545 (0.078)** (0.095) Belief 0.491 0.361 (0.049)*** (0.006)*** Constant 5.174 4.098 (1.253)*** (1.385)*** Observations 300 300 Notes: Standard errors in parentheses. ***Significant at the 1% level. **Significant at the 5% level. 3.3 The Amount of Conditional Cooperation Finally, we analyze how much of the contribution is due to conditional cooperation in both treatments. Fig. 2 plots, separately for each treatment, per period total contribution and the contribution due to conditional cooperation (we called it the CC contribution ). We defined that the CC contribution is the contributions which matched their beliefs about their partner s contributions (typically, contribution was 24 and belief was 24), and we aggregate per period the CC contributions. Contribution 200 150 100 50 0 Contribution 200 150 100 50 0 1 3 5 7 9 11 Period 13 15 CC contribution in Strangers Total contribution in Strangers 1 3 5 7 9 11 Period 13 15 CC contribution in Partners Total contribution in Partners Fig. 2. Total contribution and CC contribution in both Partners and Strangers. 7

100 80 Percentage 60 40 20 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 Period CC contribution in Partners CC contribution in Strangers Fig.3. Percentage of CC contribution to the per period total contribution Figures 2 and 3 convey two findings. First, the percentage of CC contribution to total contribution across 15 periods was significantly higher for Partners than for Strangers (t-test, p < 0.01). Specifically, these are 79.7% and 39.3% in Partners and Strangers, respectively. Second, in Fig. 3, the percentage of CC contribution to total contribution significantly increased over time, but that of Strangers significantly decreased over time (Spearman rank correlation test, p < 0.01). 4. Conclusion We obtained three findings in this current experiment. First, the contribution and belief in the Partners design are higher than in the Strangers design. Second, there is a positive correlation between contribution and belief in both the Strangers and the Partners design. Third, 79.7% and 39.3% of contributions in the Partners and the Strangers, respectively, were motivated by conditional cooperation, and there is a significant difference between the two. Taken together, in the Partners design, subjects contributed to the public good mainly by motivation from conditional cooperation, whereas in the Strangers design, contribution was motivated by not only conditional cooperation but also another motive. Thus, the difference in contributions between Strangers and Partners cannot be fully explained by only difference in belief. Croson (1996) and Palfrey and Prisbrey (1996) mentioned that the Strangers design exhibited more variance in the contributions, and their suggestion is consistent with the current experimental result. The remaining puzzle is the motivation of contribution in the Strangers design, and it remains to be explored in future work. 8

Acknowledgments We are grateful to the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science for providing the funds to conduct the experiments for this study. I thank Hiroshi Nakano and Katsuhiko Nishizaki for helping me run the experimental sessions. References Andreoni, J. and Croson, R. (2008) Partners versus Strangers: Random Rematching in Public Goods Experiments in Plott, C. and Smith, V. (Eds.), Handbook of Experimental Economics Results, North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 776 783. Brier, G. W. (1950) Verification of forecasts expressed in terms of probability Monthly Weather Review, 78(1), 1 3. Croson, R. (1996) Partners and strangers revisited Economics Letters, 53, 25 32. Croson, R. (2007) Theories of commitment, altruism and reciprocity: Evidence from linear public goods games Economic Inquiry, 45(2), 199 216. Fischbacher, U. (2007) z-tree: Zurich Toolbox for Ready-made Economic Experiments Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171-178. Fischbacher, U. and Gächter, S. (2010) Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public goods experiments American Economic Review, 100(1), 541 556. Keser, C. and van Winden, F. (2000) Conditional cooperators and voluntary contributions to public goods Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 102(1), 23 39. Palfrey, T. and Prisbrey, J. (1996) Altruism, reputation, and noise in linear public goods experiments Journal of Public Economics, 61, 409 427. Sonnemans, J., Schram, A. and Offerman, T. (1999) Strategic behavior in public good games: When partners drift apart Economics Letters, 62, 35 41. Yamakawa, T., Okano, Y. and Saijo, T. (2009) Non-kindness in Public Goods Experiments mimeo. 9