TIME DISCOUNTING FOR PRIMARY AND MONETARY REWARDS *

Similar documents
Time discounting for primary and monetary rewards

Procrastination and Impatience. Ernesto Reuben Paola Sapienza Luigi Zingales

Procrastination and Impatience

Procrastination and Impatience

Instant Gratification and Self-Control in an Experiment with Children and Teenagers

Experimental evidence 1

Supporting Information. Demonstration of effort-discounting in dlpfc

Title. Author(s)Takahashi, Taiki. CitationMedical Hypotheses, 65(4): Issue Date Doc URL. Type. File Information

Present Bias and Everyday Self-Control Failures

Time Discounting: Delay Effect and Procrastinating Behavior

Memory and Discounting: Theory and Evidence 1

Money Earlier or Later? Simple Heuristics Explain Intertemporal Choices Better Than Delay Discounting Does

Framing Effects in Intertemporal Choice: A Nudge Experiment

Mini-Course in Behavioral Economics Leeat Yariv. Behavioral Economics - Course Outline

TIME PREFERENCE AND ADDICTIVE CONSUMPTION: EXPERIMENTAL AND THEORETICAL APPROACHES. A Dissertation YUE ZHANG

Dual or unitary system? Two alternative models of decision making

Dual or unitary system? Two alternative models of decision making

Perception of Anticipatory Time in Temporal Discounting

Academic year Lecture 16 Emotions LECTURE 16 EMOTIONS

The Discounted Utility Model

Does time inconsistency differ between gain and loss? An intra-personal comparison using a non-parametric. elicitation method (A revised version)

Discounting of Monetary and Directly Consumable Rewards Sara J. Estle, Leonard Green, Joel Myerson, and Daniel D. Holt

Integrated versus segregated accounting and the magnitude effect in temporal discounting

Running head: SUBJECTIVE TIME PERCEPTION AND IMPATIENCE 1

Don t stop thinking about tomorrow: Individual differences in future self-continuity account for saving

Introduction to Behavioral Economics Like the subject matter of behavioral economics, this course is divided into two parts:

THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN ADDICTION AND REWARD BUNDLING: AN EXPERIMENT COMPARING SMOKERS AND NON-SMOKERS

Decision biases in intertemporal choice and choice under uncertainty: Testing a common account

WITHIN-SUBJECT COMPARISON OF REAL AND HYPOTHETICAL MONEY REWARDS IN DELAY DISCOUNTING MATTHEW W. JOHNSON AND WARREN K. BICKEL

Instructions for use

Supplementary Information

The Value of Nothing: Asymmetric Attention to Opportunity Costs Drives Intertemporal Decision Making

Veronika Grimm, Friederike Mengel. Let me sleep on it: Delay reduces rejection rates in Ultimatum Games RM/10/017

Time-Inconsistent Generosity: Present Bias across Individual and Social Contexts

The Emergence of Male Leadership in Competitive Environments. Ernesto Reuben, Pedro Rey-Biel, Paola Sapienza, Luigi Zingales

Subjective Hazard Rates Rationalize Irrational Temporal Preferences

Daniel Read, Christopher Y. Olivola, David J. Hardisty. Full terms and conditions of use:

Contagion Effects in Intertemporal Decision Making

Amount of Reward Has Opposite Effects on the Discounting of Delayed and Probabilistic Outcomes

FAT DEBTORS: TIME DISCOUNTING, ITS ANOMALIES, AND BODY MASS INDEX

Working Over Time: Dynamic Inconsistency in Real E ort Tasks

Does Working Memory Load Lead to Greater Impulsivity? Commentary on Hinson, Jameson, and Whitney (2003)

Examining the Constant Difference Effect in a Concurrent Chains Procedure

CALIFORNIA STATE UNIVERSITY, NORTHRIDGE THE EFFECTS OF IMPULSIVITY AND DEPLETED SELF-CONTROL ON TEMPORAL DISCOUNTING

Temptation and Self Control Evidence. Hauser et al. [2010] Evidence on Temptation and Self Control. Temptation and commitment in the laboratory

An Experiment on Time Preference and Misprediction in Unpleasant Tasks

Addiction in the Quasi-Hyperbolic Model

Volume 36, Issue 3. David M McEvoy Appalachian State University

Economics 101A (Lecture 13) Stefano DellaVigna

Problems Seem to Be Ubiquitous 10/27/2018. (1) Temptation and Self Control. Behavioral Economics Fall 2018 G6943: Columbia University Mark Dean

People Do Not Discount Heavily in Strategic Settings, but They Believe Others Do

OPTIMAL TIME-INCONSISTENT BELIEFS: MISPLANNING, PROCRASTINATION, AND COMMITMENT

Sweet Future: Fluctuating Blood Glucose Levels Affect Future Discounting. X.T. Wang ( 王晓田 ) Robert D. Dvorak The University of South Dakota

1. Would you prefer $54 today, or $55 in 117 days? [ ] larger reward in the specified number of days

Behavioral Economics - Syllabus

What Causes Delay Discounting? Andrea M. Angott

Choice and Procrastination

Volume Title: Risky Behavior among Youths: An Economic Analysis. Volume URL:

DELAYED REWARD AND COST DISCOUNTING. JAMES G. MURPHY Auburn University. RUDY E. VUCHINICH and CATHY A. SIMPSON University of Alabama, Birmingham

TIME DISCOUNTING AND SMOKING BEHAVIOR UNDER TAX HIKES

IMPATIENCE AND GRADES: DELAY-DISCOUNT RATES CORRELATE NEGATIVELY WITH COLLEGE GPA

Education and Preferences: Experimental Evidences from Chinese Adult Twins


A Model of Dopamine and Uncertainty Using Temporal Difference


Delay discounting: concepts and measures

Whois Behavioral? Cognitive Ability and Anomalous Preferences

Reward Systems: Human

Delay discounting, food reward, and eating in the absence of hunger

The Neural Basis of Financial Decision Making

Evidence for a Magnitude Effect in Temporal Discounting With Pigeons

Problems Seem to Be Ubiquitous 3/2/2017. (1) Temptation and Self Control. Behavioral Economics Spring 2017 Columbia University Mark Dean

Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization

Lecture 2: Learning and Equilibrium Extensive-Form Games

The Role of Psychological Connectedness to the Future Self in Decisions Over Time. University of Chicago, Booth School of Business

Econ 219B Psychology and Economics: Applications (Lecture 4)

Peer Influence and Addiction Recurrence

September Abstract

Memory and Discounting: Theory and Evidence 1

Impatience as Intertemporal Egoism

Modeling the Interplay Between Affect and Deliberation

HERO. Rational addiction theory a survey of opinions UNIVERSITY OF OSLO HEALTH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PROGRAMME. Working paper 2008: 7

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES NUDGES IN EXERCISE COMMITMENT CONTRACTS: A RANDOMIZED TRIAL. Jay Bhattacharya Alan M. Garber Jeremy D.

The neural mechanisms of inter-temporal decision-making: understanding variability

Time Preferences, Health Behaviors, and Energy Consumption

Sunk Decision Points: A Unified Theory of the Endowment Effect and Present Bias

Social Preferences of Young Adults in Japan: The Roles of Age and Gender

Interval Effects: Superadditivity and Subadditivity in Intertemporal Choice

IN DECISION NEUROSCIENCE

Discounting Future Pain: Effects on Self-Reported Pain

Journal of Research in Personality

Smoking, Wealth Accumulation and the Propensity to Plan

scope insensitivity and the mere token effect

Behavioral Economics Comes of Age

Waiting to Choose * Michael A. Kuhn University of Oregon. Alex Imas Carnegie Mellon University. Vera Mironova University of Maryland.

Behavioural Economics University of Oxford Vincent P. Crawford Michaelmas Term 2012

Discounting Time and Time Discounting: Subjective Time Perception and Intertemporal Preferences

Write your identification number on each paper and cover sheet (the number stated in the upper right hand corner on your exam cover).

Laurens Verhoef. The Effects of Labeling on Consumption Behavior. MSc Thesis

WORKING P A P E R. The Effect of Education on Time Preferences FRANCISCO PEREZ-ARCE WR-844. March 2011

Transcription:

TIME DISCOUNTING FOR PRIMARY AND MONETARY REWARDS * ERNESTO REUBEN Columbia University and IZA PAOLA SAPIENZA Northwestern University, NBER, and CEPR LUIGI ZINGALES University of Chicago, NBER, and CEPR ABSTRACT This paper reports a positive and statistically significant relation between short-term discount rates elicited with a monetary and a primary reward (chocolate). The relation is most evident among people who like chocolate and are hungry. This finding suggests that high short-term discount rates are related to an underling individual trait, consistent with models of presentbiased preferences. Date of this version: September 2009 Keywords: time preferences; hyperbolic discounting; intertemporal choice JEL classification: C91, D90, D01 * We thank the Templeton Foundation for financial support. Note: This is the author's version of a work that was accepted for publication in Economics Letters. Changes resulting from the publishing process, such as peer review, editing, corrections, structural formatting, and other quality control mechanisms may not be reflected in this document. Changes may have been made to this work since it was submitted for publication. A definitive version was subsequently published in http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2009.10.020.

There is considerable evidence indicating individuals are highly impatient. In particular, they exhibit higher discount rates in the short run than in the long run (Frederick et al., 2002). This result has significant implications for how we model intertemporal decision-making (Strotz, 1955-56). In most of the experiments, short-term discount rates are measured using monetary rewards delivered at different moments of time (e.g. Thaler, 1981; Kirby, 1997). Unfortunately, since money is fungible, it might be inadequate for this purpose. In particular, access to credit decouples money from consumption, which poses difficulties for how to interpret intertemporal choices (Cubitt and Read, 2007). An alternative is to elicit discount rates using primary goods, which are less fungible. 1 However, goods have important disadvantages: first, immediate consumption of a good easily leads to satiation; second, comparisons between individuals are more complicated as their desire for a good might vary; third, goods introduce additional uncertainty with respect to the future (e.g., I might not know how much I will want a piece of chocolate next Monday afternoon); and fourth, some goods are not easily divisible in small-enough units to provide accurate discount-rate measures. In this paper, we test whether discount rates elicited with these two different approaches are correlated. This exercise is important for two main reasons. First, a significantly positive correlation between the two suggests that we are indeed measuring an underling characteristic of individuals, which gives support to the use of models of present-biased preferences such as the quasi-hyperbolic discounting model (Phelps and Pollak, 1968; Laibson, 1997) and dual-system models (Bernheim and Rangel, 2004; Fudenberg and Levine, 2006). 2 Second, the existence or not of this 1 Even with goods, discount rates might not be accurate. Although it is harder, it is still possible to reschedule one s intertemporal consumption with primary rewards (see, Cubitt and Read, 2007). 2 We do acknowledge that a positive correlation is not necessarily the result of an underlying preference for immediacy. It could also be due to other sources, such as transaction costs. However it does suggest that it is due to individual differences. 1

correlation can enlighten us on the ultimate source of this present-bias: whether it comes from an impatience for the utility coming from consumption or whether it is an impatience toward instant gratification, even when the source of that gratification is not instant consumption (as in the case of the monetary reward). In spite of money being fungible, there are reasons to think that discount rates elicited with money and chocolate are correlated. In particular, neurological data suggests that individuals derive utility from receiving money irrespective of whether it is immediately used or not. For instance, the same limbic areas are activated when individuals make intertemporal choices with monetary rewards (Mc Clure et al., 2004) and with an immediate-consumption good (Mc Clure et al., 2007). If money is seen as a carrier of reward that provides a utility jolt when received (i.e., acts like a good, Knutson et al., 2001), then monetary rewards can measure impatience. There are few papers that elicit discount rates with both monetary and primary rewards. To the best of our knowledge, they all use consumption of addictive substances for addicted people and hypothetical choices. They consistently find that addicts have higher discount rates than non-addicts and that they discount money at a lower rate than the addictive substance (for a survey see, Green and Myerson, 2004). Our study uses a more common good (chocolate) and real instead of hypothetical choices. Most importantly, we look at normal MBA students rather than addicts and we concentrate on the relation between the two discount rates as opposed to their respective levels. 1. The Experiment In order to elicit short-run discount rates, we gave participants two sets of nine choices. Each choice was between an amount x today and a larger amount (1 + r)x in one week. Hence, by gradually increasing the interest rate r, we observe the r at which a participant switches from x today to (1 + r)x in one week. We refer to this switching 2

point as the participant's discount rate. At the end, one choice was randomly chosen from each set and implemented. In one set, x was a check for $50 and r equaled: 0.00, 0.01, 0.03, 0.05, 0.07, 0.09, 0.10, 0.15, and 0.20. Since r = 0.01 already implies an annual interest rate of 67.76%, we expect participants who are exponential discounters to switch between r = 0.00 and r = 0.01. In the other set, x was 5 Leonidas Napolitain chocolates and r equaled: 0.00, 0.05, 0.10, 0.15, 0.20, 0.40, 0.60, 0.80, and 1.00. 3 We used these chocolates because they are a well regarded but not easily available. In this way, choosing the later delivery implied forgoing the consumption of the chocolate that day. Furthermore, the small size of each chocolate made it unlikely that participants would be satiated. Checks and chocolates were received at the end of experiment or one week later after a class scheduled at the same time as the experiment. In addition, participants self-reported their fondness for chocolate and how hungry they felt at that moment. The experiment was conducted in October 2007 with MBA students. The experimental procedures and the instructions are available in Reuben et al. (2008). 2. Results Figure 1 shows the distribution of discount rates elicited with money (A), which we denote as rm, and with chocolate (B), which we denote as rc. In both cases, we observe a strong preference for immediacy. The average rm equals 5.46%, and the average rc equals 28.77%. 4 However, when elicited with money, 3 The values of r for chocolate differ from those for money because of technical constraints. We could not reliably cut chocolates into smaller fractions than quarters, which implied at least a 5% return. We could have increased the amount of chocolates, but we feared this would cause satiation. 4 Consistent with other studies, discount rates for the good are higher than for money. Only 15.79% of the participants have switching points that are consistent with discounting chocolate and money at the same rate. The majority (78.95%) discount chocolate at a higher rate than money. This difference could be due to the different ranges of r, or to a magnitude effect ($50 are worth more than 5 chocolates, Green et al., 1997). 3

35% (A) Money 35% (B) Chocolate % of participants 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% % of participants 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 5% 0% 0% 0.00 0.01 0.03 0.05 0.07 0.09 0.10 0.15 0.20 >0.20 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.40 0.60 0.80 1.00 >1.00 One-week discount rate FIGURE 1 DISTRIBUTION OF DISCOUNT RATES ELICITED WITH MONEY AND CHOCOLATE there is an important fraction of participants who switch as exponential discounters (it is actually the modal choice): 33.33% switch at rm = 1%. With chocolate, only 17.54% of the subjects switch at rc = 5%, and the modal choice is rc = 20%, which corresponds to waiting a week to receive one additional chocolate. Next, we turn to the main purpose of this study, which is to observe the relationship between rm and rg. We find a positive and statistically significant relationship between rm and rc. This can be seen in the first row of Table 1, which presents a regression with rm as the dependent variable and rc as the independent variable (plus a constant). The coefficient for rc is positive and statistically significant. 5 According to the estimate, a one standard deviation increase in rc is associated with an increase of 0.35 standard deviations in rm. Figure 2 shows the scatterplot of the data and the estimated regression line. Subsequently, we study the effect of taste and hunger. To study the effect of these variables, we divide participants into those who like chocolate (report an above-average 5 We get very similar estimates if we censor rm at its maximum and minimum values (Tobit estimates, coefficient = 0.101, p = 0.007) and if we run the regression only for participants with rg 20% (i.e., participants who might dislike chocolate fractions, OLS estimates, coefficient = 0.081, p = 0.034). 4

Discount rate with money >0.20 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.00 0.00 0.20 0.40 0.60 0.80 1.00 >1.00 Discount rate with chocolate FIGURE 2 SCATTERPLOT OF THE DISCOUNT RATES ELICITED WITH MONEY AND CHOCOLATE fondness for it) and those who dislike it (below-average fondness). Similarly, we divide participants into those that are hungry (above-average hunger) or not hungry (belowaverage hunger). 6 The combined variables have an effect the average rc: for those who like chocolate and are hungry (not hungry) it equals 29.25% (29.33%) and for those who dislike chocolate and are hungry (not hungry) 30.00% (25.91%). In Table 1, we show the results of running the previous regression for participants that like/dislike chocolate and are hungry or not. Hunger and fondness for chocolate have an important effect on the relationship between discount rates. For not-hungry participants, regardless of their passion for chocolate, the relationship between discount rates is weaker and no longer statistically significant. For hungry participants who dislike chocolate, the coefficient is of similar magnitude as the ones for not-hungry participants but is (weakly) statistically significant. A marked difference is observed for hungry participants who like chocolate. For these participants the coefficient is much 6 The questions used were: how much do you like chocolate? and how hungry are you right now? The answers were given in seven-point scales that ranged from: not at all to my favorite food/extremely hungry. 5

TABLE 1 REGRESSIONS OF THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN DISCOUNT RATES Note: OLS regressions with rm as the dependent variable and rg as the independent variable. Robust standard errors in parenthesis. ***, **, * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels. Coefficient for rg Constant R 2 Obs. All 0.091 *** (0.032) 2.840 *** (0.857) 0.125 57 Not hungry & dislikes chocolate Hungry & dislikes chocolate Not hungry & likes chocolate Hungry & likes chocolate 0.057 (0.035) 4.896 * (2.297) 0.078 11 0.069 * (0.035) 1.383 (1.164) 0.243 11 0.076 (0.060) 3.027 * (1.506) 0.087 15 0.233 ** (0.095) -0.613 (2.030) 0.306 20 larger a one standard deviation change in rc is associated with a change of 0.55 standard deviations in rm and statistically significant. 7 In summary, we find that discount rates elicited with money and discount rates elicited with chocolate are strongly correlated, in particular for participants who both like chocolate and are hungry at the time of the experiment. 3. Conclusions Consistent with the idea that high short-term discount rates are related to a trait, we show that people who exhibit impatience with monetary rewards also do so with nonmonetary rewards, particularly, among people who like the primary reward (chocolate) and are hungry (i.e., those who really want chocolate). 7 Testing whether the coefficient of hungry participants who like chocolate is bigger than those of other groups, gives the following p-values: vs. not hungry and dislike chocolate p = 0.05; vs. not hungry and like chocolate p = 0.06, and vs. hungry and dislike chocolate p = 0.09. 6

References Bernheim, D.B. and A. Rangel (2004). Addiction and cue-triggered decision processes. American Economic Review 94: 1558-1590. Cubitt, R.P. and D. Read (2007). Can intertemporal choice experiments elicit time preferences for consumption? Experimental Economics 10: 369-389. Frederick, S., G. Loewenstein, and T. O Donoghue (2002). Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature 40: 351-401. Fudenberg, D. and D. Levine (2006). A dual self model of impulse control. American Economic Review 96: 1449-1476. Green, L. and J. Myerson (2004). A discounting framework for choice with delayed and probabilistic rewards. Psychological Bulletin 130: 769 792. Green, L., J. Myerson, and E. Mcfadden (1997). Rate of temporal discounting decreases with amount of reward. Memory & Cognition 25: 715-723. Kirby, K.N. (1997). Bidding on the future: Evidence against normative discounting of delayed rewards. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General 126: 54-70. Knutson, B., C.M. Adams, G.W. Fong, and D. Hommer (2001). Anticipation of increasing monetary reward selectively recruits nucleus accumbens. The Journal of Neuroscience 21: RC159. Laibson, D. (1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112: 443-447. McClure, S.M., D. Laibson, G. Loewenstein, and J.D. Cohen (2004). Separate neural systems value immediate and delayed monetary rewards. Science 306: 503-507. McClure, S.M., K.M. Ericson, D.I. Laibson, G. Loewenstein, and J.D. Cohen (2007). Time discounting for primary rewards. The Journal of Neuroscience 27: 5796-5804. Phelps, E.S. and R.A. Pollak (1968). On second-best national saving and gameequilibrium growth. Review of Economic Studies35: 85-199. Reuben, E., P. Sapienza, and L. Zingales (2008). Time discounting for primary and monetary rewards. MPRA working paper 10650. 7

Strotz, R.H. (1955-56). Myopia and inconsistency in dynamic utility maximization. Review of Economic Studies 23:165-80. Thaler, R.H. (1981). Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency Economics Letters 8: 201-207. 8