How to Better Reduce Confirmation Bias? The Fit Between Types of Counter-Argument and Tasks

Similar documents
An Understanding of Role of Heuristic on Investment Decisions

Behavioral Finance 1-1. Chapter 5 Heuristics and Biases

Gender specific attitudes towards risk and ambiguity an experimental investigation

DEMOGRAPHICS AND INVESTOR BIASES AT THE NAIROBI SECURITIES EXCHANGE, KENYA

Experimental Testing of Intrinsic Preferences for NonInstrumental Information

Understanding Managerial Decision Risks in IT Project Management: An Integrated Behavioral Decision Analysis Perspective

INVESTOR S PSYCHOLOGY IN INVESTMENT DECISION MAKING: A BEHAVIORAL FINANCE APPROACH

ANALYSIS OF PROSPECT THEORY ON EQUITY INVESTMENT DECISION MAKING A BEHAVIOURAL PERSPECTIVE

Does the Selection of Sample Influence the Statistical Output?

The Influence of Hedonic versus Utilitarian Consumption Goals on the Compromise Effect. Abstract

PSYCHOLOGY : JUDGMENT AND DECISION MAKING

Shaping Consumer Perception to Motivate Online Shopping: A Prospect Theory Perspective

UNIVERSITY OF DUBLIN TRINITY COLLEGE. Faculty of Arts Humanities and Social Sciences. School of Business

FAQ: Heuristics, Biases, and Alternatives

Nudges: A new instrument for public policy?

Chapter 1 Review Questions

Heuristics & Biases:

Teorie prospektu a teorie očekávaného užitku: Aplikace na podmínky České republiky

G646: BEHAVIORAL DECISION MAKING. Graduate School of Business Stanford University Fall 2007

Investment Committee Decisions: Potential Benefits, Pitfalls, and Suggestions for Improvement

Representativeness Heuristic and Conjunction Errors. Risk Attitude and Framing Effects

Academic year Lecture 16 Emotions LECTURE 16 EMOTIONS

Assessment and Estimation of Risk Preferences (Outline and Pre-summary)

#28 A Critique of Heads I Win, Tails It s Chance: The Illusion of Control as a Function of

The Psychology of Inductive Inference

Sunk Cost and Target Achievement Biases in Subsequent IS-Outsourcing Decisions

Comparative Ignorance and the Ellsberg Paradox

Exploring the Impact of Instant Messaging (IM) on User Performance and Perceived Workload

Bargain Chinos: The influence of cognitive biases in assessing written work

The innate effect of Bias

Inconsistent Inference in Qualitative Risk Assessment

Are We Rational? Lecture 23

International Journal of Economics And Business Management

Trust in E-Commerce Vendors: A Two-Stage Model

Behavioural models. Marcus Bendtsen Department of Computer and Information Science (IDA) Division for Database and Information Techniques (ADIT)

Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition

Behavioral Biases in Underwriting: Implications for Insurers

Strategic Decision Making. Steven R. Van Hook, PhD

The Decision Making Process

MBA SEMESTER III. MB0050 Research Methodology- 4 Credits. (Book ID: B1206 ) Assignment Set- 1 (60 Marks)

Understanding Social Norms, Enjoyment, and the Moderating Effect of Gender on E-Commerce Adoption

Psychological. Influences on Personal Probability. Chapter 17. Copyright 2005 Brooks/Cole, a division of Thomson Learning, Inc.

The effect of decision frame and decision justification on risky choice

Behavioral Economics and Health: A Discussion. Jacob Glazer. Faculty of Management, Tel Aviv University and Department of Economics, Boston University

Analyzing Framing Effecty by an Experiment among Students in Turkey

Behavioral Finance 1-1. Chapter 6 Overconfidence

STRATEGIC COST ADVICE AND THE EFFECT OF THE AVAILABILITY HEURISTIC C J FORTUNE

The Influence of Framing Effects and Regret on Health Decision-Making

THE INTERACTION OF SUBJECTIVITY AND OBJECTIVITY IN THE PROCESS OF RISKY INVESTMENT DECISION MAKING

Relational aspects of information, time, and risk within a decisional context.

Learning Objectives. Learning Objectives 17/03/2016. Chapter 4 Perspectives on Consumer Behavior

School of Psychology. Professor Richard Kemp. Cognitive Bias: Psychology and Forensic Science

Risk attitude in decision making: A clash of three approaches

Explaining Aspects of Economic Behavior with the Help of Quantitative Methods

Worse Than Chance? Performance and Confidence Among Professionals and Laypeople in the Stock Market

An Investigation of Factors Influencing Causal Attributions in Managerial Decision Making

Confirmation Bias. this entry appeared in pp of in M. Kattan (Ed.), The Encyclopedia of Medical Decision Making.

It is Whether You Win or Lose: The Importance of the Overall Probabilities of Winning or Losing in Risky Choice

Impact of Cognitive Biases in Investment Decisions of Individual Investors in Stock Market

Susceptibility to anchoring effects: How openness-toexperience influences responses to anchoring cues

The Gender Differences in the Effect of Twosidedness E-WOM Presentation Order on Product Attitude

Physicians' Acceptance of Web-Based Medical Assessment Systems: Findings from a National Survey

UPDATING SMALL WORLD REPRESENTATIONS IN STRATEGIC DECISION- MAKING UNDER EXTREME UNCERTAINTY

Thinking Like a Researcher

Examples of Feedback Comments: How to use them to improve your report writing. Example 1: Compare and contrast

What is Experimental Economics? ECO663 Experimental Economics. Paul Samuelson once said. von Neumann and Morgenstern. Sidney Siegel 10/15/2016

Well I Never! Risk Perception & Communication

Value From Regulatory Fit E. Tory Higgins

Trading Success Overcoming Fear In Trading. By Lyle Wright

AN INVESTIGATION OF DECISION- MAKING AND THE TRADEOFFS INVOLVING COMPUTER SECURITY RISK

ORGANISATIONAL BEHAVIOUR

Management Science Letters

BIASES IN THE DECISION-MAKING PROCESS AND POSSIBILITIES OF OVERCOMING THEM

Wendy J. Reece (INEEL) Leroy J. Matthews (ISU) Linda K. Burggraff (ISU)

Sense-making Approach in Determining Health Situation, Information Seeking and Usage

Advances in Environmental Biology

Framing the frame: How task goals determine the likelihood and direction of framing effects

Some Thoughts on the Principle of Revealed Preference 1

ASSOCIATION FOR CONSUMER RESEARCH

City, University of London Institutional Repository

Reasoning with Uncertainty. Reasoning with Uncertainty. Bayes Rule. Often, we want to reason from observable information to unobservable information

Loss and extremeness aversion: studying the influence of temporal distance

Chapter 1 Thinking Critically with Psychological Science

QUALITY IN STRATEGIC COST ADVICE: THE EFFECT OF ANCHORING AND ADJUSTMENT

Freedom of choice and stimulus familiarity modulate the preference for ambiguity

The Psychology of Trading Tools and Techniques for Minding the Markets by Dr. Brett Steenbarger

Investor s Disposition Error at Emerging Market: Evidence for Experiential and Rational Thinking Styles

GUEN DONDÉ HEAD OF RESEARCH INSTITUTE OF BUSINESS ETHICS

Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game

[1] provides a philosophical introduction to the subject. Simon [21] discusses numerous topics in economics; see [2] for a broad economic survey.

Advancing Use of Patient Preference Information as Scientific Evidence in Medical Product Evaluation Day 2

Evaluation of investor behavior: Do investors respect their own limits?

Anchoring Heuristic and the Estimation of Accounting and Financial Indicators

National Culture Dimensions and Consumer Digital Piracy: A European Perspective

Anticipated Emotions as Guides to Choice

C/S/E/L :2008. On Analytical Rigor A Study of How Professional Intelligence Analysts Assess Rigor. innovations at the intersection of people,

INSENSITIVITY TO PRIOR PROBABILITY BIAS IN OPERATIONS MANAGEMENT CONTEXT

The Perception of Own Death Risk from Wildlife-Vehicle Collisions: the case of Newfoundland s Moose

The Knowing-Doing Gap

Concluding Remarks. Mental illness is ubiquitous. Mental illnesses exist at the extremes of normal behavior

Transcription:

Association for Information Systems AIS Electronic Library (AISeL) SAIS 2010 Proceedings Southern (SAIS) 3-1-2010 The Fit Between Types of Counter-Argument and Tasks Hsieh Hong Huang kory@nttu.edu.tw Neeraj Parolia Sheng Pao Shih Follow this and additional works at: http://aisel.aisnet.org/sais2010 Recommended Citation Huang, Hsieh Hong; Parolia, Neeraj; and Shih, Sheng Pao, " The Fit Between Types of Counter-Argument and Tasks" (2010). SAIS 2010 Proceedings. 7. http://aisel.aisnet.org/sais2010/7 This material is brought to you by the Southern (SAIS) at AIS Electronic Library (AISeL). It has been accepted for inclusion in SAIS 2010 Proceedings by an authorized administrator of AIS Electronic Library (AISeL). For more information, please contact elibrary@aisnet.org.

HOW TO BETTER REDUCE CONFIRMATION BIAS? THE FIT BETWEEN TYPES OF COUNTER-ARGUMENT AND TASKS Hsieh-Hong Huang Dept. of Information Science and Management Systems National Taitung University, Taiwan kory@nttu.edu.tw Neeraj Parolia Dept. of e-business and Technology Management Towson University nparolia@towson.edu Sheng-Pao Shih Department of Information Management Tamkang University,Taiwan sbao@mail.tku.edu.tw ABSTRACT Confirmation bias is a driver of problematic decision making. People search information supporting current beliefs and ignore real critical evidence. Counter-argument i.e. providing evidences opposite to preferred beliefs was shown to have an effect on reducing confirmation bias. This study advances past studies by separating counter-arguments into two types and examining their effects in different stock investment contexts. We attempt to show that different types of counter-arguments are needed under different decisional contexts. Keywords Confirmation bias, counter-argument, de-bias, risk aversion INTRODUCTION Human beings are boundedly rational. Problematic subjective judgments during cognitive processes prohibit people from making the right decision by distracting them from rationally accessing and utilizing information, which then lead to overtrading and low profitability in financial markets. Researchers refer to these problematic subjective judgments as cognitive biases. Behavioral decision making literatures indicate that intrinsic cognitive biases exist in the decision making process and these cognitive biases have a negative impact on decision making (Arnott, 2006). Therefore, contemporary computer supported decision making tools were developed to reduce biases mentioned by Tversky and Kahneman (1974). However, the rationalization of a decision-making process by formalizing it within a computer-based information system does not seem to make the process itself more rational (George et al., 2000). The bias that operates without the information system continues to operate within it (e.g. Jiang et al., 1995, Barber and Odean, 2002). To fill this gap, some researchers have entered significant efforts in understanding how DSS can provide de-bias function to eliminate confirmation bias during decision making process (e.g. Huang, 2009). The results revealed that confirmation bias can be effectively reduced through providing counter-arguments. Although previous research has built a foundation by showing that counter-arguments can effectively reduce negative consequences of confirmation bias, over simplified research setting limits the value of findings and implications. There is a need to explore the concept in a more complex setting in order to understand phenomenon thoroughly. For example, counterargument is solely defined as information conflicting to current beliefs but, however, it can be separated in advance into two types argument opposite to the preferred one or supporting alternatives. It is reasonable to suspect that these two types of counter-argument may not always generate the same effect. Furthermore, past research only employed one type of task (to arrange money into two stocks) in the experiment. However, in the stock market, traders may buy or sell stock in their daily life - that is, different types of task. Putting these two concepts together, we believe that people tend to weigh different types of counter-argument differently when they face different decision tasks (e.g. buy or sell). Specifically, based on risk aversion perspective (Elton and Gruber, 1997; Kahneman and Tversky, 1979), we predict that, to avoid risk, information which shows that the target stock won t perform well will generate more countering effect when traders attempt to buy it. In contrast, when traders attempt to sell one of several stocks in hand, more countering effects can be generated by providing evidences which show that other stocks in hand may be perform worse. 39

In a summary, although the effect of counter-argument in specific task has been shown by past research, whether DSS should provide different types of counter-argument under different tasks is not clear. Therefore, under computer-supported decision making context, this study focuses on understanding how different types of counter-argument may generate different level of effect under different types of decision tasks - buy or sell stock. Experiments will be conducted to examine these proposed ideas. LITERATURE REVIEW AND HYPOTHESES In this section, we first review the literature about confirmation bias and its impact on decision making. In the following section, we then define counter-argument and classify it into two types. Research models and hypotheses are then developed based on the review. Confirmation bias and its impact on decision outcome Most people have a bias while carrying out a concept or verifying an assumption. Within this bias, people tend to restrict their attention to a favored hypothesis, prefer treatment of evidence supporting existing beliefs, look only or primarily for positive cases, overweight positive confirmatory instances, and see what one is looking for (Nickerson, 1998). That is, decision-makers seek confirmatory evidence and do not search for disconfirming information. (Russo et al., 1996; Heath, 1996; Arnott, 2006). Wason (1960) defined it as confirmation bias and indicated that individuals tend to seek evidence in support of their assumptions, instead of searching for and comparing evidence against their assumptions. Confirmation bias may defeat decision making in several ways (Nickerson, 1998). First, people tend to restrict themselves to the preferred hypotheses only and ignore, intentionally or unintentionally, other possible hypotheses. Second, people tend to look for information fitting to their existing beliefs. Third, with information at hand, people tend to overweigh the information that fits with their beliefs and disconfirm the information that does not fit their hypothesis. Even in ambiguous situations, where both positive and negative supports are provided, people only need a little positive evidence to support their hypothesis (Pyszczynski and Greenberg, 1987). For example, medical doctors may overweigh some test results and underweigh, or even ignore other possible explanations while diagnosing (Casscells et al. 1978). The consequence of overweighing some evidence and underweighing other evidence is reaching a wrong conclusion. With formed beliefs, decision makers tend to focus on specific hypothesis only or, if multiple hypotheses are considered, choose the information which fit their beliefs. They may also distort the information and explain it in ways which fit their beliefs. The effects of confirmation bias reflect on two broadly discussed decisional characteristics: decisional adjustment and confidence. Decision makers suffer from error anchoring and inadequate adjustment (Tverskey and Kahneman, 1974). Adjustment refers to the tendency for decision maker to be influence by additional information. Additional evidence may be positive or negative and people adjust their beliefs in either direction (increase or decrease) according to the additional information (Ashton and Ashton, 1988). Tversky and Kahneman (1974) indicated that, in general, it is difficult for people to anchor in the correct value initially and insufficient or inappropriate adjustment is made while concerning other positive or negative information related to the initial decision. Subjects may adjust their decision toward the center (no difference between two options) or move away from center (strong preference toward one target). People move their decision to center when they are less confident toward their prior preference. This happens when decision makers receive information opposite to the prior preference. In contrast, decision makers move their final decision to one end when they receive information fitting with their preference, which increases the degree of confidence. With confirmation bias, moving away from center is expected because decision makers actively read information which fits with their prior preference. H1a: People with confirmation bias tend to adjust their decision away from the center to their previous preference. Decision confidence refers to the subjects beliefs regarding their investing performance and their perceived probability that their decisions are correct (Peterson and Pitz, 1988; Davis and Kottemann, 1994). It is not rare for people to be over optimistic and under estimate the risk and over estimate their problem solving ability (Kahneman and Riepe, 1998). This happens in many professional fields, such as financial investing, and tends to be greater for difficult tasks. Griffin (1996) indicates that optimism serves as a driving force for over estimating that the favored outcome will occur. Confidence tends to be higher when people seek support for their initial view rather than to look for disconfirming evidence (Russo and Schoemaker, 1992). Therefore, we hypothesize that H1b: People with confirmation bias tend to be more confident toward their decision. 40

De-bias: Computer-mediated counter-argument Various de-bias functions were proposed to counter confirmation bias and those propositions were examined by empirical studies (Keren, 1990; Fishoff, 1982; Bazerman, 2002; Russo and Schoemaker, 1992). Theory indicates that once one s belief is formed, it is not easy to change if there is no other stimulus (Hoch and Deighton, 1989). Counter arguments encourage decision makers to consider why their initial assumptions might be wrong or ask others to give them counter arguments. For example, Block and Harper (1991) found that warnings can usefully reduce the effect caused by anchoring and insufficient adjustment, although it cannot be eliminated completely. Moreover, George et al. (2000) conducted a similar experiment to test whether the existence of warning can reduce or eliminate anchoring and adjustment biases. The result shows that the cognitive biases that exist under without a computer-supported environment continue to exist within it. Conceptual and empirical studies indicate that there is a need to provide stimulus to challenge one s belief so that the decision making process can be more rational (Russo and Schoemaker, 1992; Gorman, 2005). Empirical studies also showed that computer-mediated counter-argument can effectively reduce irrational confidence and allow decision makers to adjust their decision to the right direction. In previous study, the moderating effect of counter-argument has been proposed and confirmed (Huang, 2009). Counter-argument refers to evidence opposite to current beliefs and it can be separated into two types: alternative-support and self-opposite. Alternative-support type of counter-argument refers to arguments providing positive evidence which show that other non-preferred options are as good as or superior than the preferred one. On the other hand, self-opposite type of counter-argument refers to arguments providing negative evidence which show that the preferred options may not perform as good as expected or even worse than other non-preferred options. Although the effect of counter argument has been illustrated, past research has mixed these two types of counter-argument and, therefore, cannot answer whether different types of counter-argument can generate different effects. To answer this question in this study, we adopt risk aversion concept and attempt to show that the reduction of the effect of confirmation bias by counter argument is determined by whether counter-argument fits the task in hand. The fit between the types of counter-argument and task Kahneman and Tversky (1979) found that traditional expect utility theory can not fully explain the human decision-making behavior under uncertainty and risky situations. To explain it, they proposed the Prospect theory. According to reflection effect (one effect of prospect theory), decision makers are risk-averse in the positive domain and are risk-seeking in the negative domain. Kachelmeier and Shehata (1992) demonstrated that people tend to make different decisions depending on the choice task which involves buying or selling stock. Decision makers tend to perform risk-seeking behaviors while buying and tend to perform risk-aversion behaviors while selling stock (Kachelmeier and Shehata, 1992; Holt and Laury, 2002). Since traders buy and sell stock in their daily life and possess different attitudes toward risk, this elicits our interest in investigating the effect of counter-argument under these two tasks. Furthermore, we explore which type of counter-argument can fit into the task and generate better effect in de-biasing. In the following, we discuss the effect of counter-argument type in different types of task. The buying task When people attempt to add one a stock among several stocks into the portfolio, according to confirmation bias theory, they tend to read information which shows this stock is profitable or shows that other stocks are non-profitable. That is, people search and read information which fit into their existing mental model. They ignore those messages opposite to existing mental model because those messages are considered as inappropriate or wrong. Therefore, counter-argument is required to remind decision maker that other options may be also profitable (other-support) or the preferred one may not be so profitable (self-opposite) (Kahneman and Tversky, 1979; Kachelmeier and Shehata, 1992; Holt and Laury, 2002). However, according to risk aversion perspective, people try to avoid potential risk which may lead to the loss of money. Therefore, traders tend to pay more attention to evidence which shows that the preferred stock may not as profitable as expected because it represents a high possibility of losing money. On the other hand, people tend to pay less attention to evidence which shows that other non-preferred stock may be as profitable because the preferred target is still profitable. The consequence of confirmation bias is abnormal decisional confidence and inadequate adjustment of decision. These consequences imply that decision makers overweigh messages which fit into their pre-preference and ignore important messages during the decision making process. Therefore, we hypothesize that H2a: Under buying context, compared with subjects who receive alternative-support counter-argument, confirmation bias has less effect on decision adjustment for subjects who receive self-opposite computer-mediated counter-argument. 41

H2b: Under buying context, compared with subjects who receive alternative-support counter-argument, confirmation bias has less effect on decision confidence for subjects who receive self-opposite computer-mediated counter-argument. The selling task When people attempt to sell a portion or total of one stock in hand, according to confirmation bias theory, they attempt to check evidences which show that the target stock is not worse to be possessed or other stocks in the portfolio are more worth to be kept in the future (Elton and Gruber, 1997; Kachelmeier and Shehata, 1992). Therefore, counter-arguments refer to evidences which show that the selected stock (to sell) may perform much better than expected (self-opposite) or other stocks may perform much worse than expected (alternative-support). Under this context, risk aversion refers to avoiding losing money from selling the wrong stock. Therefore, to traders, alternative-support type of counter-argument tend to draw more attention from traders since those evidences imply that keeping those stocks equals to losing money. That is, risk increases if they choose to keep those stocks. In contrast, self-opposite type counter-arguments generate less impact because they only show that the selected target may not perform as bad as expected which is far less important than losing money through keeping those stocks may decrease the total value. Therefore, we hypothesize that H2c: H2d: RESEARCH METHODS Under selling context, compared with subjects who receive self-opposite type of counter-argument, confirmation bias has less effect on decision adjustment for subjects who receive alternative-support type computer-mediated counter-argument. Under selling context, compared with subjects who receive alternative-support counter-argument, confirmation bias has less effect on decision confidence for subjects who receive self-opposite computer-mediated counter-argument. In this project we focus on the moderating effect of counter argument, an experiment will be conducted to test listed hypotheses. The model is showed in Figure 1. A stock investment task is selected because DSS are intensively adopted to support stock investment decision making to cope with high uncertainty and process data in large quantities. A GUI-based DSS, with 4GL programming language and a relational database management system, will be developed for the experiment. Actual designing activities will follow Hung et al., (2007) s recommendations. A total of 256 subjects are expected to be recruited. Since our predefined task is stock investment, we will focus on subjects with stock or other investing experience. Task Type Purchasing Selling Fit Computer-Mediated Counter-Argument Self-Opposite Alternative-Support H2 Confirmation Bias H1 Decision Outcome Adjustment Confidence EXPECTED RESULTS Figure 1. Research model A couple implications for academia can be gleaned from this project. First, past study has shown the existing of confirmation bias in stock investment task. This study aims at providing another piece of evidence to show how confirmation bias take places in different decision making context. Second, we attempt to show that different type of counter-argument is needed for different type of tasks. For practitioners, this project serves as an example which shows the decision support systems designer that how different types of de-bias means can be incorporated into the system design to effectively counter cognitive biases. 42

ACKNOWLEDGEMENT We gratefully acknowledge financial support from National Science Council of Taiwan (NSC 98-2410-H-143-017-). REFERENCES 1. Arnott, D. 2006. "Cognitive biases and decision support systems development: a design science approach," Information Systems Journal (16:1), pp. 55-78. 2. Ashton, A. H. and Ashton, R. H. 1988. "Sequential belief revision in auditing," The Accounting Review (63:4), pp. 623-641. 3. Barber, B. M. and Odean, T. 2002. "Online Investors: Do the Slow Die First?", The Review of Financial Studies (15: S2), pp. 455 487. 4. Bazerman, M. H. 2002. Judgment in Managerial Decision Making, New York: Wiley. 5. Block, R. A. and Harper, D. R. 1991. "Overconfidence in estimation: Testing the anchoring-and-adjustment hypothesis," Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes (49:2), pp. 188-207. 6. Casscells, W., Schoenberger, A., and Graboys, T. B. 1978. "Interpretation by physicians of clinical laboratory results," New England Journal of Medicine (299:18), pp. 999-1001. 7. Davis, F. D. and Kottemann, J. E. 1994. "User Perceptions of Decision Support Effectiveness: Two Production Planning Experiments," Decision Sciences (25:1), pp. 57-76. 8. Elton, E. J. and Gruber, M. J. 1997. "Modern portfolio theory, 1950 to date," Journal of Banking & Finance (21:11-12), pp. 1743-1759. 9. George, J. F., Duffy, K., and Ahuja, M. 2000. "Countering the anchoring and adjustment bias with decision support systems," Decision Support Systems (29:2), pp. 195-206. 10. Gorman, M. E. 2005. "Heuristics, moral imagination, and the future of technology," Behavioral and Brain Sciences (28:4), p. 551. 11. Griffin, D. W. and Varey, C. A. 1996. "Towards a consensus on overconfidence," Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes (65:3), pp. 227-231. 12. Heath, C. 1996. "Do People Prefer to Pass Along Good or Bad News? Valence and Relevance of News as Predictors of Transmission Propensity," Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes (68:2), pp. 79-94. 13. Hoch, S. J. and Deighton, J. 1989. "Managing What Consumers Learn from Experience," Journal of Marketing (53:2), pp. 1-20. 14. Holt, C. A. and Laury, S. K. 2002. "Risk Aversion and Incentive effects," The American Economic Review (92:5), pp. 1644-1655. 15. Huang, H. H. 2009. Understanding the Role of Computer-Mediated Counter-Argument in Countering Confirmation Bias. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, National Chung Cheng University, Taiwan. 16. Hung, S. Y., Ku, Y. C., Liang, T. P., and Lee, C. J. 2007. "Regret avoidance as a measure of DSS success: An exploratory study," Decision Support Systems (42:4), pp. 2093-2106. 17. Jiang, J. J., Muhanna, W, and Pick, R. 1996. "The Impact of Model-Context Sensitive Help Messages In a DSS: User Confidence," Computers in Human Behavior (12:2), pp. 193-207. 18. Kahneman, D. and Riepe, M. W. 1998. "Aspects of investor psychology," Journal of Portfolio Management (24:4), pp. 52-65. 19. Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. 1979. "Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Choice Under Risk," Econometrica (47:2), pp. 263-91. 20. Keren, G. 1990. "Cognitive aids and debiasing methods: can cognitive pills cure cognitive ills," In Cognitive biases, J. P. Caverni, J. M. Fabre, and M. Gonzalez (eds.), Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp. 523-552. 21. Nickerson, R. S. 1998. "Confirmation bias: A ubiquitous phenomenon in many guises," Review of General Psychology (2:2), pp. 175-220. 22. Peterson, D. K. and Pitz, G. F. 1988. "Confidence, Uncertainty, and the Use of Information," Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning Memory, and Cognition (14:1), January, pp. 85-92. 43

23. Pyszczynski, T. and Greenberg, J. 1987. "Self-regulatory preservation and the depressive self-focusing style: A selfawareness theory of reactive depression," Psychological Bulletin (102:1), pp. 122-138. 24. Russo, J. E., Medvec, V. H., and Meloy, M. G. 1996. "The Distortion of Information during Decisions," Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes (66:1), pp. 102-110. 25. Russo, J. E. and Schoemaker, P. J. H. 1992. "Managing overconfidence," Sloan Management Review (33:2), pp. 7-17. 26. Wason, P. C. 1960. "On the failure to eliminate hypotheses in a conceptual task," The Quarterly Journal of Experimental Psychology (12:3), pp. 129-140. 44