Assess the view that a minimum price on alcohol is likely to be an effective and equitable intervention to curb externalities from drinking (25)

Similar documents
Alcohol etc. (Scotland) Bill. Royal College of Psychiatrists Scotland

Price-based measures to reduce alcohol consumption

BRIEFING: ARGUMENTS AGAINST MINIMUM PRICING FOR ALCOHOL

Minimum Unit Pricing Saves Lives

Alcohol (Minimum Pricing) (Scotland) Bill. Wine and Spirit Trade Association

Alcohol Minimum Unit Pricing: Mythbuster

Alcohol (Minimum Pricing) (Scotland) Bill. WM Morrison Supermarkets. 1.1 Morrisons has 56 stores and employs over 14,000 people in Scotland.

Briefing: The rising affordability of alcohol

7. Provide information - media campaigns such as know your units, labelling on drinks

ECONOMICS. Component 1 Microeconomics. AS LEVEL Exemplar Candidate Work. For first teaching in 2015.

Health First: an alternative alcohol strategy for the UK. Linda Bauld

Minimum Unit Pricing & Banning Below Cost Selling: Estimated policy impacts in England 2014/15

David v Goliath: Minimum Unit Pricing for Alcohol in Scotland

Alcohol etc. (Scotland) Bill ASDA

GUIDANCE ON MINIMUM UNIT PRICING FOR RETAILERS GUIDANCE ON MINIMUM UNIT PRICING FOR RETAILERS

Alcohol etc. (Scotland) Bill. Chivas Brothers Ltd and Pernod Ricard

Alcohol in Ireland: Tackling the Financial Hangover

Employee Handbook of the Royal College of Physicians of Ireland. RCPI Policy Group on Alcohol Pre Budget Submission

THE IMPACT OF PRIVATIZATION ON ALCOHOL CONSUMPTION AND STATE REVENUES

Health, Social and Economic Impact of Alcohol. Stakeholders workshop. 20 January 2005

Minimum alcohol price policies in action: The Canadian Experience

In preparation : The impact of raising minimum alcohol prices in Saskatchewan, Canada: Improving public health while raising government revenue?

The Economics of Alcohol and Cancer/Chronic Disease

EPHA Briefing: Q&A on European Legal Challenge to Minimum Unit Pricing (MUP) of Alcohol Does Europe have an Alcohol Problem?

MENTAL HEALTH DISORDERS: THE ECONOMIC CASE FOR ACTION Mark Pearson Head of Department, OECD Health Division

Age Controls in Reducing Binge Drinking in Germany

2015 Pre Budget Submission

Pamela S. Erickson, President Public Action Management, PLC April 28-29, 2010

Table 1. Summary of the types of alcohol taxes applied by category of alcohol product. 12

ECONOMICS Component 2 Exploring Economic Issues

Portman Group response on Alcohol Bill to Health and Sport Committee

FACT SHEET Alcohol and Price. Background. 55 million European adults drink to dangerous levels.

Budget 2018 analysis

Jonathan Gornall. Under the influence. How the alcohol industry sabotaged minimum unit pricing


Alcohol (Minimum Pricing) (Scotland) Bill. SABMiller

How we drink, what we think

Sainsbury s plc. Alcohol etc (Scotland) Bill. 39 of our 825 stores are in Scotland (28 supermarkets, 11 convenience stores).

Fraser of Allander Institute

Policy Planning and Choice: TOOLKIT. Guide to Feasible Interventions. Adapted from:

Shetland Licensing Forum and Shetland Alcohol and Drug Partnership. Alcohol (Licensing, Public Health and Criminal Justice) (Scotland) Bill

Connolly, Kevin and Lisenkova, Katerina and McGregor, Peter (2018) The Economic Impact of Changes in Alcohol Consumption in the UK.

Minimum Unit Pricing of Alcohol

The Effects of Excise Tax on Beer Consumption

Alcohol consumption, harm and policy responses in Europe. Dr Lars Møller Programme Manager World Health Organization Regional Office for Europe

n/e/r/a ALCOHOL IN LONDON: A COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS A Final Report for the Greater London Authority Prepared by NERA January 2003 London

GERMANY. Recorded adult (15+) alcohol consumption by type of alcoholic beverage (in % of pure alcohol), Spirits 20%

Model-based appraisal of minimum unit pricing for alcohol in the Republic of Ireland. September 2014

Alcohol, Harm and Health Inequalities in Scotland

Modelling to assess the effectiveness and cost-effectiveness of. public health related strategies and interventions to

Alcohol taxes and restrictions could curb problem drinking, but are hard to sell

A proposal for changes to BC liquor prices in order to reduce harm from alcohol consumption

Alcohol as a public health issue in croatia. Croatian Institute of Public Health Prof. Danijela Štimac Grbić, MD.,PhD.,MPH.

Attitudes, Awareness and Understanding

Cider Duty in the Republic of Ireland

Scottish Health Action on Alcohol Problems. Alcohol (Licensing, Public health and Criminal Justice) (Scotland) Bill

THE ECONOMICS OF TOBACCO AND TOBACCO TAXATION IN BANGLADESH

What the AMPHORA project says for European alcohol policy

ROMANIA. Upper-middle Income Data source: United Nations, data range

NORWAY. Recorded adult (15+) alcohol consumption by type of alcoholic beverage (in % of pure alcohol), Other 2% Wine 31%

Idaho State Police Alcohol Beverage Control

KAZAKHSTAN. Upper-middle Income Data source: United Nations, data range

ALCOHOL AND CANCER TRENDS: INTERVENTION SCENARIOS

ALCOHOL (MINIMUM PRICING) (SCOTLAND) BILL

SLOVENIA. Recorded adult (15+) alcohol consumption by type of alcoholic beverage (in % of pure alcohol), Spirits 13%

Consultation on the review of existing legislation on the structures of excise duties on alcohol and alcoholic beverages

Effective Interventions for Reducing Alcohol-relatedHarms

POLICY BRIEF. Government-Run Liquor Stores The Social Impact of Privatization JOHN PULITO & ANTONY DAVIES, PHD EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

ALABAMA PRESENTATION

Attitudes, Awareness and Understanding

ARMENIA. Lower-middle Income Data source: United Nations, data range

A Scottish adaptation of the Sheffield Alcohol Policy Model

Minimum pricing of alcohol and its impact on consumption in the UK

Expectations of the project and some general information

The Idaho Model of Distilled Spirits Distribution. Citizen Owned for the Benefit of All

Contact. Nesta Lloyd Jones, Policy and Public Affairs Manager, the Welsh NHS Confederation. Tel:

Contact for questions or clarifications: GLOBAL SURVEY ON ALCOHOL AND HEALTH CONTACT INFORMATION. Date: / / (Day/Month/Year)

Cannabis use carries significant health risks, especially for people who use it frequently and or/begin to use it at an early age.

Violence Prevention A Strategy for Reducing Health Inequalities

Estimating Illegal Activities in Denmark

A Snapshot: Medical Marijuana in Rural New Mexico & Benefits of Legalizing Adult Use of Marijuana in Rural New Mexico

1. This paper reports on the findings of the independent evaluation into the impact of the increases in tobacco excise duty.

Partnership between the government, municipalities, NGOs and the industry: A new National Alcohol Programme in Finland

Mark Scheme (Results) Summer Pearson Edexcel GCE AS Level in Economics A (8EC0) Paper 01 Introduction to Markets and Market Failure

SLIDE 5: Graph of Trends in Federal Alcoholic Beverage Taxes

Cannabis Legalization August 22, Ministry of Attorney General Ministry of Finance

ATTITUDES AND BEHAVIOURS

Permanent Link:

UP IN SMOKE: THE SOCIAL COST OF TOBACCO EXCISE

Salford s Alcohol Strategy

CCPA. Balancing Convenience with Social Responsibility. Liquor Regulation in Manitoba CANADIAN CENTRE FOR POLICY ALTERNATIVES MAN ITOBA

Regulatory Impact Statement. Increase in Tobacco Excise and Equivalent Duties

San Francisco Alcohol Mitigation Fee Michele Simon, JD, MPH Research and Policy Director Marin Institute

They are updated regularly as new NICE guidance is published. To view the latest version of this NICE Pathway see:

Time allowed: the total time for papers ECN1/1 and ECN1/2 together is 1 hour

ALCOHOL CONTROL POLICY IN LITHUANIA

Six months on from the implementation of MUP, what can we say about changes in alcohol sales in Scotland? Key points

AUSTRALIAN CHRONIC DISEASE PREVENTION ALLIANCE. Submission to Senate Standing Committee on Community Affairs

LITHUANIA. Upper-middle Income Data source: United Nations, data range

DRINK SMART, HOME SAFE

Transcription:

Assess the view that a minimum price on alcohol is likely to be an effective and equitable intervention to curb externalities from drinking (25) Introduction A minimum price of 50 pence per unit has been introduced in Scotland from 1 st May 2018 but not in England where the government has chosen to introduce a ban on selling alcohol under a permitted price which means that a can of average strength lager cannot be sold for less than 41p and a standard bottle of vodka cannot be sold for less than 9.06. This essay will assess whether a price floor is likely to work and also be equitable to different stakeholders. Point 1 The first argument for having a minimum price on alcohol is that excessive drinking leads to negative externalities from consumption which is a major cause of market failure and leads to significant social costs. Anti-social behaviour associated with binge drinking impacts not just those who over-consume but impose external costs on the health service and uses up the scarce resources of the police and criminal justice system. Alcohol abuse can also lead to increased absenteeism from work and lower labour productivity in the long run. The effect of negative externalities is shown in my analysis diagram where the marginal social cost exceeds marginal private cost leading (in the absence of any intervention) to a deadweight loss of social welfare. A research report from the University of Sheffield estimated the following annual costs arising from alcohol miss-use: NHS costs 3.5bn, alcohol-related crime 11bn and lost productivity due to alcohol 7.3bn. In this situation, some form of government intervention is clearly justified and the Scottish government argues that a minimum price floor is better for targeting harmful binge drinking, while leaving the more moderate drinker relatively unaffected. In this sense, it is an equitable policy. AQA Diagram: Negative externalities from consumption (MSB<MPB)

EdExcel Diagram: Negative externalities where MSC>MPC Evaluation However, there is a danger that intervention can lead to one or more government failures. One argument is that putting a minimum price on alcohol will lead to

unintended consequences. For example, banning cheap alcohol at festivals and other events might lead young people to switch to using cheaper non-alcoholic drugs instead. If drinkers cannot afford alcohol at legally-imposed minimum prices, they may turn to shadow markets so we might expect a rise in cross-border shopping as consumers go to supermarkets in England to get their alcohol at a cheaper price. If people want to get around a regulation, they will normally find a way do so if there is an obvious net financial benefit. Point 2 A second argument in favour of minimum unit pricing for alcohol is that enforcing a minimum unit price will encourage drinks manufacturers to reformulate their products so that any price increase for the consumer is limited. For example, in 2012, AB InBev (one of the world s biggest brewers) reduced the alcohol content of their beers for the UK market, from 5% to 4.8%. They have seen sales rise strongly in recent years suggesting that focusing on lower-strength beers and zero-alcohol drinks might generate supernormal profits in the long run. A minimum unit price for alcohol could have similar effects to what we have seen occur with the phrased introduction of a sugar tax where many firms have moved quickly to reduce the sugar content of drinks to reduce their liability to pay tax. Reformulation helps lower the risks of alcohol-fueled violence and therefore can be a justified intervention in the market. Evaluation Critics of the minimum alcohol price counter by saying that it is a tax on responsible drinkers and that many families on average or below-average incomes will be badly affected. Research from the Institute of Fiscal Studies has found that 5% of households in the UK buy more than 30% of all alcohol. Why should people who drink in moderation have to pay a higher price? A legally enforced minimum price might be seen as having a regressive effect on poorer households. The wine and spirits industry has lobbied against the Scottish minimum price arguing that it is inconsistent with the operation of the free market for the state to intervene on price and that it is a barrier to trade. They claim that lower sales of alcoholic drinks will cost jobs in the UK, both from manufacturing and from reduced revenues of corner shops, pubs and other retailers. Point 3 A third argument in favour of minimum unit pricing for alcohol focuses on the actual behaviour of consumers. One cause of alcohol-related violence comes from people preloading drinks at home before they head out to pubs and clubs. A minimum price for beers and spirits sold in supermarkets would help to curb drinking at home because the marginal private cost of doing so has increased. In my analysis diagram

below, we see how a higher price will cause a contraction of demand, the size of which depends on the price elasticity of demand for different drinks. The level of consumer surplus falls as a result. A possible positive spillover from an end to super-cheap alcohol available from supermarkets is that more people will choose to go to pubs instead, perhaps helping to reverse the pattern of pub closures seen for a number of years. Evaluation Although in theory higher prices will reduce affordability and therefore limit demand and (ultimately) consumption, in practice consumers will always find ways around a regulation. One effect might be an increase in home-brewing of beer, gin and wine which might then lead to a rise in alcoholic poisoning and additional external costs. Youngers drinkers in particular might look to get around the legal minimum price by finding illicit alcohol in shadow markets. They are at greater risk of suffering the effects of information failure which is another significant cause of market failure. This is also a policy that could be quite expensive to enforce. Compliance costs can reduce the net benefits of an intervention.

Final reasoned comments Critics of the minimum price claim that it is both ineffective in changing behaviour and is unfair (inequitable) to responsible drinkers and hits lower income families the most. They also claim that the main effect of the minimum price will be to increase the monopoly profits of the drinks industry at the expense of the consumer welfare of the majority of consumers. Some economists argue that an orthodox indirect tax on alcohol is a better strategy and it also creates tax revenues for the government which can then be earmarked to help fund health and education programmes. Behavioural economists might make the point that nudging consumers - for example by making them more aware of the social consequences of their actions - can be as effective as an intervention in the price mechanism. Overall, I would argue that a minimum price per unit of alcohol is a justified intervention. Society is waking up to the huge long-term social costs of heavy drinking across all levels of household income. A minimum price is required to reduce consumption closer towards the social optimum and there are signs that it is and will bring about a change in the behaviour both of consumers and producers. The rapid growth of low or zero-alcohol lagers and wines is a reflection of a shift in revealed preferences. The evidence suggests that heavy drinkers tend to buy and consume cheap and high-strength alcohol available away from pubs so this policy could well be quite effective in the years ahead.