Health care policy evaluation: empirical analysis of the restrictions implied by Quality Adjusted Life Years

Similar documents
NICE Guidelines for HTA Issues of Controversy

Making Economic Evaluation Fit for Purpose to Guide Resource Allocation Decisions

WHAT TO DO IN ABSENCE OF HEAD TO HEAD CLINICAL TRIAL DATA. Lead the economic evaluation group at CHERE, University of Technology, Sydney

Health Economics 101: PPI prescriptions in the Emergency Room

An Introduction to Costeffectiveness

Advancing Health Economics, Services, Policy and Ethics

Health technology The study compared three strategies for diagnosing and treating obstructive sleep apnoea syndrome (OSAS).

Men s treatment preferences for prostate cancer: results from a discrete choice experiment. Funded by NHMRC Project & Program Grants

Waiting times. Deriving utility weights for the EQ-5D-5L

Using Health Economics to Inform the Development of Medical Devices. Matthew Allsop MATCH / BITECIC

Pharmacoeconomics: from Policy to Science. Olivia Wu, PhD Health Economics and Health Technology Assessment

Using Discrete Choice Experiments with duration to model EQ-5D-5L health state preferences: Testing experimental design strategies

Study Protocol: Comparison of Inconsistency between Time Trade Off and Discrete Choice Experiments in EQ-5D-3 L Health State Valuations

Valuing nonfatal health risk: Inferring monetary values from QALYs

Time Trade-Off and Ranking Exercises Are Sensitive to Different Dimensions of EQ-5D Health States

Qu est-ce que la santé? Regard critique sur les QALYs et analyse d autres paramètres pour mesurer les gains en santé

A. Introduction to Health Economics. Dr Alan Haycox Reader in Health Economics Health Economics Unit University of Liverpool Management School

European Experience and Perspective on Assessing Value for Oncology Products. Michael Drummond Centre for Health Economics, University of York

2/20/2012. New Technology #1. The Horizon of New Health Technologies. Introduction to Economic Evaluation

To what extent do people prefer health states with higher values? A note on evidence from the EQ-5D valuation set

Real-world observational data in costeffectiveness analyses: Herceptin as a case study

Food for thought. Department of Health Services Research 1

Principles of decisions making at NICE

Minimizing Cost per Quality-Adjusted Life Year Gained?

Folland et al Chapter 4

Probability Weighting and Utility Curvature in QALY-Based Decision Making

Cost-benefit evaluations with applications in pricing & reimbursement of pharmaceuticals and in traffic safety

Department of Economics

Economics of Frailty. Eamon O Shea

Type of intervention Secondary prevention and treatment; Other (medication coverage policy design).

DRAFT PLEASE DO NOT CITE WITHOUT PERMISSION OF THE AUTHORS. Risk-Benefit Preferences Versus Measured Utility: A Comparison of Methods

Health Services Research and Health Economics. Paul McCrone Institute of Psychiatry, King s College London

Final Exam - section 2. Thursday, December hours, 30 minutes

Australian Technical Advisory Group on Immunisation Then and Now. Professor Terry Nolan AO

Bringing Together Health Economics and Clinical Research

CARDIOVASCULAR DISEASE AND DIABETES:

Cost-effectiveness of urodynamic testing before surgery for women with pelvic organ prolapse and stress urinary incontinence Weber A M, Walters M D

The role of non-transparent matching methods in avoiding preference reversals in the evaluation of health outcomes. Fernando I.

Access to newly licensed medicines. Scottish Medicines Consortium

Cost-effectiveness of osimertinib (Tagrisso )

A CASE STUDY OF VALUE OF INFORMATION

Methods of eliciting time preferences for health A pilot study

It is Whether You Win or Lose: The Importance of the Overall Probabilities of Winning or Losing in Risky Choice

Health Technology Assessment and the Demands of the Fourth Hurdle Experiences from TLV in Sweden

Value Based Health Care in the UK: NICE, VBP and the Cost-effectiveness Threshold. Eldon Spackman, MA, PhD

Cost-Utility Analysis (CUA) Explained

The Cost-Effectiveness of Individual Cognitive Behaviour Therapy for Overweight / Obese Adolescents

NICE DSU TECHNICAL SUPPORT DOCUMENT 8: AN INTRODUCTION TO THE MEASUREMENT AND VALUATION OF HEALTH FOR NICE SUBMISSIONS

Decisions about Pap tests: what influences women and providers?

Clinical and economic consequences of non-adherence

The Economics of Obesity

Value Function Elicitation: A Comment on Craig R. Fox & Amos Tversky, "A Belief-Based Account of Decision under Uncertainty"

Are visual attention and preferences telling us the same story about multiattributes

Herbert A. Simon Professor, Department of Philosophy, University of Wisconsin-Madison, USA

Session 6: Choosing and using HRQoL measures vs Multi-Attribute Utility Instruments QLU-C10D and EQ-5D as examples

Introducing the QLU-C10D A preference-based utility measure derived from the QLQ-C30

Japan Journal of Medicine

Valuing health using visual analogue scales and rank data: does the visual analogue scale contain cardinal information?

Health technology The use of the antihypertensive drug losartan for the prevention of stroke.

The Economic Consequences of Diabetes: More than just a health issue

Value Based Reimbursement Do we want it? Do we already have it? CADTH Symposium Vancouver, April 2011

Convincing the Payers. Saurabh Jha MBBS Assistant Professor of Radiology, University of Pennsylvania

Basic Economic Analysis. David Epstein, Centre for Health Economics, York

The Chimera of WTP for a QALY: Inconsistencies of Stated Preferences in Scenario Variations

Cost-Utility Analysis (CUA), part II

Doctors Fees in Ireland Following the Change in Reimbursement: Did They Jump?

The Use of QALY Weights for QALY Calculations

Valuing Avoided Morbidity Using Meta- Analysis: What Can Health Status Measures and QALYs Tell Us about WTP?

VALUE IN HEALTH 21 (2018) Available online at journal homepage:

Health Economic Assessment: Cost-Effectiveness Thresholds and Other Decision Criteria

A Belief-Based Account of Decision under Uncertainty. Craig R. Fox, Amos Tversky

Health Economics and Cost/Decision Analysis

Module 1 What is economics and economic evaluation?

Methods for the Statistical Analysis of Discrete-Choice Experiments: A Report of the ISPOR Conjoint Analysis Good Research Practices Task Force

Cost-effectiveness of measuring fractional flow reserve to guide coronary interventions Fearon W F, Yeung A C, Lee D P, Yock P G, Heidenreich P A

NATIONAL INSTITUTE FOR HEALTH AND CLINICAL EXCELLENCE. Technology Appraisals. Patient Access Scheme Submission Template

DECISION-MAKING UNDER RISK: EVIDENCE FROM NORTHERN ETHIOPIA 1

The role of training in experimental auctions

What does it mean for innovative technologies/medicines? Health economic evaluations and their role in health care decision making.

Report. for the Pharmaceutical Oncology Initiative Group (POI)

The cost of cancer treatment

The Economic Burden of Hypercholesterolaemia

Setting The study setting was hospital. The economic study was carried out in Australia.

Cost-effectiveness Analysis for HHS

A consistency test of the time trade-off

Analysis of Hearing Loss Data using Correlated Data Analysis Techniques

Health Economics Research Centre. The cost-effectiveness of policies to reduce radon-induced lung cancer

Study population The study population comprised a hypothetical cohort of patients with confirmed reflux oesophagitis.

Connecting commitment to self-control: Evidence from a field experiment with participants in a weight loss challenge

Review: Logistic regression, Gaussian naïve Bayes, linear regression, and their connections

Einführung ins Thema

EuroQol Working Paper Series

Addressing health equity concerns in costeffectiveness

Recognizing Ambiguity

Decisions in 4 EU countries*

National Primary Care Research and Development Centre and University of York Health Economics Consortium (NICE External Contractor)

Cost effectiveness of

Addendum to clinical guideline 131, Colorectal cancer

Access to cancer drugs: The role for a stakeholder alliance?

Transcription:

Health care policy evaluation: empirical analysis of the restrictions implied by Quality Adusted Life Years Rosalie Viney and Elizabeth Savage CHERE, University of Technology, Sydney Preliminary not for quotation

Health care policy evaluation Resource allocation decisions in health care increasingly based on cost-effectiveness analysis Australia Pharmaceutical Benefits Advisory Committee (PBAC) Medicare Services Advisory Committee (MSAC) United Kingdom National Institute of Clinical Excellence (NICE) Canada (Ontario), Denmark, Finland, Netherlands, Sweden All have formal requirements for economic evaluation for reimbursement decisions for pharmaceuticals United States Discussion of a PBAC type process for new pharmaceuticals 2

Example: Pharmaceutical Benefits Scheme PBAC required by legislation to consider costeffectiveness (among other factors) Company seeking PBS listing for a drug must submit an economic evaluation Evidence of clinical effectiveness Estimate potential health gain from new drug relative to current treatment (measure of effectiveness) Estimate additional cost of new drug relative to current treatment proposed price for new drug standardised prices for other health services Calculate incremental cost-effectiveness ratio 3

Examples of PBAC Decisions Incremental cost per additional Quality Adusted Life Year gained league table Submission $/QALY Recommendation $4,690 Recommend 2 $5,244 Recommend 3 $8,570 Recommend 4 $0,530 Recommend 5 $3,2 Recommend 6 $7,937 Not Recommend 7 $2,225 Recommend 8 $24,343 Recommend 9 $33,337 Reect Source: George B, Harris A and Mitchell A. Cost effectiveness and consistency of decision making: evidence from pharmaceutical reimbursement in Australia (99-996). Pharmacoeconomics 9:03-09 200. 4

Measures of health gain (effectiveness) Ideally want measures that are comparable across different diseases and treatments Intermediate / surrogate (clinical) outcome not comparable Life years saved Quality adusted life years saved (QALYs) 5

Estimating health gain Decision tree framework Epidemiological information used to identify disease states outcomes of treatment probability of different outcomes (proportion of a population experiencing the outcome) survival (durations) associated with different outcomes quality of life associated with different outcomes Estimate expected life years associated with each alternative (new treatment, current treatment) Not all years of life have the same value (quality) 6

Quality Adusted Life Years Quality Adustment reflects valuation of poorer health states relative to full health QALYs calculated by weighting survival time associated with each treatment outcome by a QALY weight QALY weight of for a year of life in full health QALY weights generally lie between 0 (death) and (full health) Worse than death health states permissible QALYs measure strength of preference for survival and quality of life and trade-offs between the two 7

Example: QALY Weights AIDS, CD4 count range 0-50 0.79 Arthritis, before treatment 0.609 Arthritis, after treatment 0.647 Cancer, breast, after surgery, first recurrence 0.85 Cancer, breast, after surgery, third recurrence 0.3 Cancer, prostate, metastatic, early progressive disease Proctitis/cystitis after randiation therapy for prostate cancer 0.83 0.9 Stroke, severe, motor deficit 0.03 Stroke, mild cognitive deficit 0.54 Source: Tengs, T and Wallace A. One Thousand Health-Related Quality of Life Estimates Medical Care 38(6) 583-637, 2000 8

9 Health care can be characterised as lotteries over profiles of consumption and health Treatments modify the set of lotteries Individuals will have preference orderings over alternative treatments QALY model implies restrictions on form of utility function m m T m T m m T T p c h c h p c h c h U U ;,,,,,, ;,,,, Economic underpinnings of QALYs

Outline Describe methods used to derive QALYS Outline the restrictions on preferences imposed by the QALY model Describe a discrete choice experiment designed to investigate preferences for health care Test restrictions on preferences implied by the QALY model 0

QALYs Measure the value of a particular health state relative to full health, ignoring consumption Under the QALY model U h, h2,..., ht vh t T t where v(h t ) is the quality (utility) weight of health state in period t ie identical additive separable function in each period

Quantifying QALY weights Involves experiments using standard gambles and time trade-offs These rely on restrictions on preferences over consumption and health status over time. 2

QALY model: Standard gamble A p h for time T Full health, FH for time, T Specify h Find p such that utility of the gamble, B, is equal to A - the certainty of health state h for T years ie B p. v FH T 0 v h T - p Immediate death p h vfh Normalise: v(fh) = v 3

QALY model: Time trade-off FH Find x such that utility of the health state for time T, h is equal to the utility of full health for a proportion x of T years ie v h. T vfh. xt h x v h vfh xt T 4

Note: Only attributes of the health state and time enter the experiment In both cases the experiment sets T Individual responses are averaged to determine the QALY weight attached to health state 5

QALY model: Application Say a treatment improves health status for a proportion, p, of the population undergoing the treatment from h (with QALY weight Q ) to h 2 (with QALY weight Q 2 ) and lengthens expected survival time from T to T 2 The effectiveness per individual in terms of QALYs gained is equal to p (Q 2 T 2 -Q T ) p,h, h 2, T,T 2 are derived from clinical data Q 2 and Q are derived from the TTO/SG experiment; T in the experiment is unrelated to T or T 2 ; p in the experiment unrelated to p. 6

QALYs: Policy Evaluation Effectiveness measured by QALY gain combined with cost to give a C/E ratio. If the C/E ratio lies below some threshold level, the intervention is accepted. The threshold indicates willingness to pay per QALY. Setting the threshold effectively monetises effectiveness. 7

QALY Restrictions Under what restrictions on preferences is costeffectiveness analysis based on QALYs likely to lead to health care resource allocation that reflects individuals preferences? 8

Literature Pliskin, Shephard and Weinstein (980) Bleichrodt, Wakker and Johannesson (997) Miyamoto, Wakker, Bleichrodt and Peters (998) Preferences defined over a constant health state and survival Bleichrodt and Quiggin (997) Preferences defined over non-constant health states over time Expected utility and Rank dependent expected utility Bleichrodt and Quiggin (999) Preferences defined over non-constant health states and consumption over time 9

QALY restrictions: B&Q (999) VNM expected utility Marginality Symmetry Standard gamble invariance Zero condition 20

QALY restrictions: marginality Let y G = ($20, H ); y B = ($5, H 2 ); H >H 2 With marginality an individual is indifferent between G: (y B, y B ) with prob=/2 and (y G, y G ) with prob=/2 G2: (y B, y G ) with prob=/2 and (y G, y B ) with prob=/2 Both G and G2 have the same probability of y G in both periods and of y B in both periods. Marginality excludes all complementarity across time periods, such as a dislike for variation or a desire to avoid a bad outcome in both periods. 2

QALY restrictions: symmetry Requires that resequencing does not change utility: U 2 T t y, y,... y U y t Inconsistent with positive time preference. T 22

QALY restrictions: standard gamble invariance For all levels of consumption, c and c c, h c, h, p; c, h, c, h c, h, p ; c, h p, p Utility derived from the health state unaffected by the level of consumption 23

QALY restrictions: zero condition Less controversial U c, death Uc, death 0 24

25 Under QALY restrictions z(c) a constant i.e. Implies constant consumption over time t T t m i i m m T m T m m T T h v c z p p c h c h p c h c h U U ;,,,,,, ;,,,,

Implications of QALY restrictions EU: linear in probabilities Evaluation function for gambles is linear in probabilities. No complementarity across time periods. The utility function over sequences of consumption and health state is additively decomposable over time One-period utility functions are the same. RDEU: probability weighting function Changes the marginality condition to generalised utility independence less strict. 26

Discrete choice experiments and health care DCEs widely used in transport economics, environmental economics and marketing Used in health economics to: Explore trade-offs between attributes of health care interventions Provide monetary valuations of health care interventions Predict uptake of new programs Discrete choice experiments can provide data to explore the underlying utility function for health and health care, particularly trade-off between quality of life and survival (QALYs) 27

DCE Methods Stated preference surveys Choose preferred alternative from a series of hypothetical choice sets Alternatives described in terms of attributes Attributes varied over plausible range of levels of analytical interest Experimental design principles used to choose a sample of choice sets to allow for efficient estimation of parameters of interest 28

DCE Methods: Binary Choice P i P i U i Pr( U V i i U Pr V V i i i ik ) ik ik 29 e e V i e ' x V e i i e ' x V i e ik ' x ik

Discrete choice experiment to investigate health care preferences Choice between two alternatives: treatment (TR) and non-treatment (NT) for a hypothetical health condition. FH,T,C H,T P TR P NT TR NT - P TR Death - P NT Death 30

Attribute levels Each alternative has three, four-level, alternative-specific attributes. Cost of non treatment is zero Health state from treatment is full health or death PTR Probability of survival with treatment TTR Life expectancy if survive PRICE Price of treatment PNT Probability of survival without treatment TNT Life expectancy without treatment HS Health state without treatment 54% 0 years $20,000 39% 0 years HS 69% 20 years $40,000 59% 20 years HS2 84% 30 years $60,000 79% 30 years HS3 99% 40 years $80,000 99% 40 years HS4 3

Health states Generic health states from EQ-5D multi-attribute utility instrument Selected to be ordered, cover the range of health states and to make sense HS HS2 HS3 HS4 FH Mobility 3 2 2 2 Self care 3 2 Usual Activities 3 3 2 Pain/Discomfort 3 2 2 2 Anxiety/Depression 3 3 2 32

You have a health condition that affects your quality of life and your life expectancy. There is a treatment available for your condition and you must decide whether to have treatment or not. If you do have treatment If you do not have treatment The out of pocket cost to you is $20,000 There is no out of pocket cost to you The chances of having successful treatment or dying are: Chance of dying as a result of treatment 6% Chance of successful treatment 84% The chance of surviving or dying with this condition are: Chance of dying within one month 2% Chance of surviving 79% If treatment is successful your life expectancy is If you survive your life expectancy is 30 years 20 years 30 years 20 years Successful treatment will give you full health which means you have: No problems in walking about No problems with self care No problems peforming usual activities No pain or discomfort Not anxious or depressed Your health is affected by this condition in the following ways: Some problems in walking about No problems with self care Some problems in performing usual activities Moderate pain or discomfort Moderately anxious or depressed Would you have treatment? 33 Yes No

Survey design and data collection Six 4-level attributes = 4096 choice sets, 64 for each alternative 92 choice sets selected from the full factorial Blocked into 2 separate questionnaires, each with 6 choice sets Random sample aged 8-60 from Sydney metropolitan area door-to-door recruitment; self-completion questionnaires 347 respondents in total 34

Data Treatment was the preferred alternative in 65.% of observations Two choice sets for which 00% of respondents chose treatment 9.6% of respondents always chose treatment 3.7% of respondents always chose no treatment Remaining respondents responsive to changing alternatives 35

Methods: Testing QALY model QALY restricted specification Expected utility is given by the sum of the product of probability, time and QALY weight. In log form and imposing the QALY restrictions gives lnu lnp lnt H C TR where NT For rank dependent expected utility P is replaced by a probability weighting function gp ; the simplest specification is lng P lnp 36

Methods: Testing QALY model Unrestricted specification With the zero condition the general form is lnu with lng P H, T, C where TR NT T k H k k C. lnt H C K H k C H k C CT C lnt k C 2 C H T 2 k H k lnt 37

Notes Health states under non-treatment are ordered and dummy-effects-coded in the estimation. Loss of consumption is proxied by cost of treatment. Constant is zero for non-treatment. Cost is zero for non-treatment. The impact of full health with treatment is in the constant. Expansion is up to quadratic terms. 38

Logit results Model (unrestricted) Model 2 (QALY) Variable Coef P> z Coeff P> z Cons -0.3292 0.70 0.94 0.000 LnPtr.699 0.000 - - LnTtr 0.757 0.000 - - Cost -0.004 0.362-0.008 0.000 LnTtr_Cost -0.008 0.500 - - Costsq 0.000 0.30 - - LnPnt.4504 0.000 - - LnTnt 0.5933 0.000 - - HS -0.292 0.537-0.853 0.000 HS2 0.4063 0.20-0.68 0.00 HS3-0.469 0.85-0.386 0.000 LnTnt_HS -0.2050 0.068 - - LnTnt_HS2-0.84 0.075 - - LnTnt_HS3 0.2573 0.00 - - LnProb - -.50 0.000 LnTime 39 - - 0.60 0.000 Log likelihood -3226.699-3233.59

Tests of QALY model restrictions Equal coefficients on common TR and NT variables No interaction effects Jointly test zero coefficients on interaction variables Coefficients on probability and time variables = 40

Test of equal coefficients on common TR and NT variables ( ) P tr = Pnt chi2() = 2.36 Prob > chi2 = 0.24 CANNOT REJECT ( 2) T tr = Tnt chi2( ) = 0.62 Prob > chi2 = 0.4300 CANNOT REJECT 4

LR test on interaction effects H 0 : No interaction effects Full model Log L = -3226.6992 Constrained model Log L = -3232.6693 LR test: 2.9402 2 crit,0.05.0705 REJECT 42

Test for zero interactions in constrained model Coefficients on interaction terms = 0 lnrttr_rcost rcostsq lnrtnt_hsfx lnrtnt_hsfx2 lnrtnt_hsfx3 chi2( 5) = 0.83 Prob > chi2 = 0.0549 REJECT (JUST) 43

Test: utility function linear in probability and time ( ) ln(prob) = chi2( ) = 39.56 Prob > chi2 = 0.0000 REJECT ( 2) ln(time) = chi2( ) = 46.95 Prob > chi2 = 0.0000 REJECT 44

Conclusions Empirical analysis of this DCE does not provide support for the QALY restrictions. Suggests a more general evaluation function is required for resource allocation in health. Why the dominance of QALY model? Monetary measures of welfare gain seen as ethically troubling. B&Q: QALY model does not avoid ethical udgements. Explicit treatment of distribution is preferable. 45