Cross-racial envy and underinvestment in South African partnerships

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Cross-racial envy and underinvestment in South African partnerships"

Transcription

1 NOT FOR PUBLIC RELEASE Cambridge Journal of Economics 2008, 1 of 22 doi: /cje/ben011 Cross-racial envy and underinvestment in South African partnerships Daniel Haile, Abdolkarim Sadrieh and Harrie A. A. Verbon* Trust games are employed to investigate the effect of heterogeneity in income and 5 race on cooperation in South Africa. The amount of socio-economic information available to the subjects about their counterparts is varied. No significant behavioural differences are observed when no such information is provided. However, when the information is available, it significantly affects individual trust behaviour. The low income subjects from both racial groups invest significantly less 10 in partnerships with the high income subjects of the other racial group than in any other partnership. We attribute this behaviour to cross-racial envy, which on aggregate may lead to substantial efficiency losses. Key words: Trust game, Ethnic diversity, Income inequality, Cooperation JEL classifications: C91, J Introduction A recent hypothesis in the literature is that economic performance will be furthered by the absence of economic and ethnic divisions (see, e.g., Alesina et al., 1999; Easterly and Levine, 1997). Knack and Keefer (1997), for example, note that, for countries like Norway, Finland, Sweden, Denmark and Canada, a high degree of homogeneity both in 20 terms of income and ethnicity goes along with a high degree of economic performance. 1 The explanation behind this linkage is that people with a greater set of similar characteristics are more likely to form partnerships and start to cooperate. 2 In this paper, we examine the effect of economic and ethnic division in the case of South African society. This society is extreme in its heterogeneity, with segmentation along both 25 racial and income divides. In particular, before the breakdown of apartheid in 1994, the Manuscript received 11 September 2006; final version received 11 September 2007 Address for correspondence: Department of Economics, Tilburg University, PO Box 90153, 5000 LE Tilburg, The Netherlands; H.A.A.Verbon@uvt.nl * Wageningen University, University of Magdeburg and Tilburg University, respectively. 1 Incidentally, based on the World Social Survey measurement, these five countries also have the highest level of trust. The close correlation between trust, social homogeneity and economic performance can also be derived from the experimental results by Glaeser et al. (2000) who find that when individuals are closer socially, trust and trustworthiness tend to be higher. 2 However, as shown by Collier (2001), democracy may considerably soften the detrimental effects of ethnic diversity on economic growth. Ó The Author Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Cambridge Political Economy Society. All rights reserved.

2 2 of 22 D. Haile et al. black population 1. received less than 50% of the national income, but this share had risen to 75% in (Stewart, 2000). However, at the same time intra-racial income inequality had increased. Amongst black households the Gini index increased from 0.49 in 1970 to 0.59 in 2000, while among the whites it moved from 0.43 to 0.49 (Whiteford and 30 van Seventer, 2000). Widening income gaps within ethnic groups can imply low intra-group trust levels, next to the low trust between groups. To study both aspects of the trust problem, we conducted trust game experiments in South Africa, in which the subjects were given information about their opponents race and income characteristics. The trust game, originally 35 developed by Berg, Dickhaut and McCabe (1995), is a two-player game in which the first player, the sender, sends part of his initial endowment to the second player, the receiver. The experimenter triples the sent amount, and the receiver can then decide which part of his total endowment (the tripled transferred amount plus the initial endowment) to return to the sender. The game is called a trust game as the amount the sender transfers to 40 the receiver gives an indication of the sender s trust in the willingness of the receiver to reciprocate. Starting with the original inventors of the game, Berg et al. (1995), the trust game has also widely been dubbed the investment game, as the sender, by sending part of the endowment to the receiver, invests his money, which will generate some positive return if the latter returns a sufficiently large amount. Hence, the amount sent is 45 frequently called the investment. The trust game has emerged as one of the leading experimental instrument for the measurement of the level of cooperativeness in societies (see Camerer, 2003; Glaeser et al., 2000) We employ the trust game to assess the degree to which racial and income disparity may be degrading trust in South Africa. More specifically, the questions that we raise include 50 the following. Is the level of trust and cooperative attitude in South African society generally (disregarding specific race and income disparities) different from what has been reported in the literature on other societies? In what ways does information on the race and the income characteristics of a trading partner determine the level of trust and reciprocity in the multiply segmented South African society? The answer to the question whether 55 racial and income divides prevent subjects from investing in personal relationships is obviously vital to economic and social development, because trust and cooperation across racial and income boundaries will be necessary in order to reduce transaction costs and, thus, to enhance economic exchange and efficiency. A number of theories have been proposed to explain why inequality and ethnic 60 heterogeneity may affect the individual level of trust. Since perceived satisfaction (or happiness) is often positively correlated to the perceived relative income position in a reference group (Clark and Oswald, 1996; McBride, 2001; Solnick and Hemenway, 1998), income inequality can affect individuals well-being (Festinger, 1954; Frank, 1985; Pollak, 1976). Hence, high degrees of inequality can lead to envy and dissatisfaction thus 65 reducing trust and cooperativeness in economic relationships (Alesina and La Ferrara, 2002; Leigh, 2006). Inequality can also imply an urge to invest resources to verify the trustworthiness of the individuals with whom they interact. Zak and Knack (2001), in particular, argue that with increasing inequality the transaction costs attached to interaction with individuals of different income levels can become excessively high. 1 According to the 1996 census 77% of the 40,583,573 people in the country were black and 11% were white, while Indians (3%) and coloured (9%) people made up smaller percentages. 2 South Africa had a Gini index of 0.58 in 1997, which made it the country with the highest inequality after Brazil with a Gini index of 0.63 (World Bank, 1997).

3 Cross-racial envy and underinvestment 3 of Ethnic heterogeneity has also been shown to have a negative effect on economic activity (Alesina and La Ferrara, 2002; Bandiera et al., 2005; Leigh, 2006). A number of different causalities for this effect have been mentioned in the literature (cf. Bandiera et al., 2005). Amongst the most prominent hypotheses are that collective action is more difficult in heterogeneous communities due to increased differences in tastes, in preferences for 75 working together in ethnically mixed teams, and in the configuration of the sharing rules. Furthermore, ethnic heterogeneity may also lead to competitive and growth-reducing rentseeking activities (Alesina and La Ferrara, 2005). These effects have been studied on a local or country level by regressing aggregate measures of inequality and heterogeneity on measures of cooperation such as participation in social groups, or on economic growth 80 rates (cf. La Ferrara, 2002). While empirical studies help to reveal the correlations between trust and the socioeconomic parameters, experimental studies, such as ours, scrutinise the underlying behaviour at the individual level. In fact, several experimental studies have examined the effect of ethnicity on trust and trustworthiness. However, no study so far has attempted to 85 disentangle the ethnicity effects from the income inequality effects. Fershtman and Gneezy (2001) studied Israeli partnerships in which the individuals were informed of their partner s last name. Since last names in Israel are generally indicative of their preimmigration ethnicity, the names may be used to discriminate between partners from different ethnical origins. In fact the study showed a systematic mistrust of eastern males, 90 resulting in a lower efficiency of the partnerships they were involved in. On first sight, this outcome seems to imply a clear case for ethnic discrimination. But a closer look at the income distribution across the ethnic divide reveals that there may have been an effect of income inequality that confounded the results. Since individuals of eastern origin are much more likely to be in the lower income groups (Fershtman and Gneezy, 2001), and 95 since the actual income level of the subjects was not controlled for, it remains unclear whether the discrimination (i.e. the distrust) was towards the eastern males or towards poor males. In a study with US subjects, Eckel and Wilson (2003) found that allowing individuals to observe their partner s picture increases trust and trustworthiness. However, they also 100 found that the pictures could lead to ethnic discrimination, because minority groups (in particular African-Americans) were less likely to be trusted than the majority groups (Caucasian). Again, there was no control for the income distribution effects, which happen to point in the same direction as in the Fershtman and Gneezy (2001) study: the ethnic group that is mistrusted happens to be the ethnic group with the lower average income. 105 In a study with South African subjects, Burns (2003) conducted dictator and trust games with high school students in the greater Cape Town area. 1 To check the effect of race on the propensity to trust, subjects were shown pictures of their partners. In the dictator games, blacks are favoured by non-whites, but not by whites, who show no bias towards any race. In trust games, however, black students are trusted less by all groups, 110 including their own group. Once again, this seems to be clear evidence for the prevalence of 1 Experimental studies on trust in (South) Africa using experiments are rare. Barr (2003) conducted experiments in Zimbabwe in order to detect which factors contribute to the feeling of shared social identities within communities. Carter and Casteillo (2003) examine the level of trust for South African communities in the province of KwaZulu-Natal, investigating the difference between rural or urban communities in the degree of intra-racial trust. In a closely connected study, Haddad and Maluccio (2003) conduct householdlevel research in KwaZulu-Natal. Their results suggest that both local trust (in neighbours and extended family) and income level are important for financial group participation, which is shown to be correlated with economic prosperity.

4 4 of 22 D. Haile et al. racial discrimination, but there is no control for possible confounding effects of income inequality. As in the other two studies, the group that is being mistrusted most also represents the poorest ethnic group, leaving the question open as to whether racial or income discrimination has been detected. 115 Our experimental design allows us to disentangle the two main division lines that exist in heterogeneous societies (i.e. the racial or ethnic and the income divides) by giving subjects information both on the income level and the race of their partner. Surprisingly, we find neither a purely racial nor a purely income-based discrimination effect. Instead, we discover a strong and significant cross-racial envy effect that to our knowledge has not 120 been reported by any study so far. Envy is known to play an important role in social and economic life (Mui, 1995; Schoeck, 1966). An envious person suffers from the knowledge that another person has a greater share of the economic resources. Envious individuals, therefore, may be willing to take actions to decrease other individuals resources, even if such actions come at a strictly positive cost. 125 In the context of our trust game, if low income subjects have feelings of envy towards high income subjects, they will invest or return little when matched with a high income partner. We find no sign of envy between individuals of the same race. What we find is that low income individuals of both races display envy only in partnerships with a high income partner from the other race. This effect can be considered a robust discrimination effect, 130 because behaviour in the baseline treatment without information, which we conducted with a randomised sub-sample of our subjects, neither exhibits significant differences within the subject pool, nor significant differences when compared to the behaviour observed in earlier experiments without information. Next to envy, our experimental design also allows us to discover charity, the behavioural 135 counterpart to envy. While an envious person has incentives to decrease the payoffs of those who are better-off, a charitable person has incentives to increase the payoffs of others, and the more so the lower their income. 1 Hence, charity, in our experiment, entails investing more than one expects to receive back or returning more than the investment. The only charitable behaviour we observe pertains to high income white individuals who 140 are matched to low income black individuals. The observed effects are likely to be a remnant of the history of apartheid and antiapartheid in South Africa. The violent inter-racial tensions seem to have focused the envy across the race barrier, leaving the poor black especially envious of the rich white and the poor white especially envious of the rich black. Surprisingly, we find no pure racial 145 discrimination effect, which hints at a sense of solidarity and acceptance across races amongst individuals of the same economic segments. Furthermore, we even find some charitable behaviour across races, with charity mainly going from the rich white to the less privileged black. We proceed in the following fashion. Section 2 describes the experimental protocol. 150 Section 3 contains the results on the effects of information. In particular it discusses whether discrimination, if it exists, is based on income or on race. Section 4 works out the correlates between survey questions and experimental decisions and thereby analyses the impact of social distance on the propensity to trust. The last section concludes. 1 Our design also allows us to discover other forms of altruism, such as warm-glow altruism, in which giving is independent of the distribution of payoffs. However, we do not find any signs of such behaviour.

5 2. Experimental procedures Cross-racial envy and underinvestment 5 of The subjects played the one-shot trust game. We applied the strategy method where each subject decided how much to transfer both in the role of sender and the role of receiver. 1 Subjects knew at the start of the experiment that they had to play both roles. The role that determined the actual payoff was drawn randomly. Both sender and receiver were endowed with 20 Rand. (At the time of the experiment the exchange rate 160 was Rand.) As senders, subjects were asked to decide how much of their endowment they would like to transfer to a receiver. To decrease decision complexity and paperwork, the sender transfer was restricted to being zero or any even integer smaller or equal to 20. As receivers, subjects were asked to decide how much they would like to transfer back for each of the 11 possible amounts (0, 2,..., 20) that they may 165 have received from a sender. Additionally, each subject was asked to report both the amount expected as a return on their own transfer as a sender and the amount expected as an investment as a receiver. 2 Our treatment variable is the information that subjects received on the characteristics of their counterparts. Upon recruitment, subjects were asked to report their race 3 and 170 to assess whether they perceive their family income to be above or below the average family income in South Africa. We chose to use a perception instrument instead of an exact measurement, because it is more likely that behaviour is linked to the perception of the relative income position than to an exact measure of income differences, which is not readily accessible to most people. Based upon this self-assessment information, we 175 categorised our subjects according to their race (B 5 black; W 5 white) and their income level (L 5 low income, i.e. below average; H 5 high income, i.e. above average). In the information treatment, the information on the race and the income level of the counterpart was given to each subject before any decision was made. The information was given in the same brief and matter-of-fact manner in all information 180 sessions. No specific emphasis was put on any part of the information (see the instructions in Appendix A). In the no information treatment, no such information was given to subjects. The experimental conditions, including the number of observations for all the distinguished subject types and treatments, are summarised in Table A total of 172 subjects participated in the experiment: 94 black and 78 white. Family income was considered to be below average by 112 subjects and above average by Obviously, the population distribution at the universities is not equivalent to the distribution of race and income in the general population of South Africa. But, note that this does not disturb the internal validity of our experimental investigation, because the 190 socio-economic matching that we used in each partnership was predefined and known to the subjects. Hence, the population distribution played absolutely no role in the decisionmaking and the evaluation of the results. 1 We applied the strategy method, as we had to recruit a large part of our subjects on the spot and did not know in advance whether a counterpart for each recruited subject could be found. 2 The instructions to the subjects are contained in the Appendix. 3 In South Africa students are normally asked to indicate their race upon registering for a university or a school. Hence, asking for this information does not have to generate suspicion with the subjects regarding the experimenters intentions. No single subject objected to providing the information on their race. 4 We used an open advertisement recruiting procedure at the two universities visited. Even though the student population can be considered as biased towards the high income groups, the frequency of high income blacks in the population is so low, that we were not able to recruit as many BH subjects as we had initially planned.

6 6 of 22 D. Haile et al. Table 1. Experimental conditions and number of observations in South Africa trust game No information a Information a Total BL BH WL WH Subjects characteristics BL BH WL WH Total a In the information treatment, subjects were given both race and income level information on their counterpart before the transfer decisions were made. No such information was given at any time in the no information treatment. BL, black on low (below average) income; BH, black on high (above average) income; WL, white on low income; WH, white on high income. Note that income categories are based on subject s own self-assessment. The experimental sessions were conducted in October 2003, at the Potchefstroom University 1. (predominantly white) and at the Mafeking University (predominantly black). 195 We conducted the experiment using pen and paper. A post-experimental questionnaire, containing some general questions and some standardised items on equity preferences, was solicited from each subject after the experiment. In particular, subjects had to react to the well-known trust question from the General Social Survey (GSS), used by Knack and Keefer (1997) in their demonstration that trust is conducive to economic growth. In 200 Section 4 we will consider whether the extracted information in the questionnaire contribute to explaining the experimental results. After all sessions were completed, each subject s decision form was linked to that of another subject, respecting the predetermined matching that was recorded on the subject s decision form. 2 Next, the role of the subject in the partnership was determined randomly and with equal probabilities. Finally, the 205 subject s payoff was calculated using the linked decision forms and the subjects were paid in cash. Note that our subjects have an incentive to act according to their self-interest and not according to the perceived interest of the experimenter, because their payoffs are incentive compatible and not flat (as in many surveys and in some psychological experiments). 210 Furthermore, our subjects are not confronted with survey-like questions and receive neither explicit nor subtle hints as to what the experimenter expects to observe. In fact, in the given situation, it is rather difficult to pinpoint the socially desirable behaviour, since the game begins with a fair division (every player receives the same endowment) and trusting the other is not obviously fairness enhancing. Finally, we can verify that our 215 procedures did not create a distorting experimenter demand effect, because the responses generated in our control treatment (without information on the race or the income level of the counterpart) show no significant differences when compared with the responses observed in the original double-blind experiment by Berg et al. (1995). Their double-blind 1 Conducting the experiments was made possible by the hospitality of the Economics Department of Potchefstroom University; in particular, the support given by Professor Wim Naudé was indispensable. 2 Note that the strategy method guarantees that each decision form can be considered as an independent observation, because no interaction has taken place, when subjects make their decisions. Furthermore the strategy method guarantees that we can match unbalanced groups without letting any subject play more than once and without deceiving subjects.

7 Cross-racial envy and underinvestment 7 of 22 procedure safeguards against experimenter demand effects, because it ensures that 220 subjects are fully aware of the fact that the experimenter cannot link observed behaviour to their identities. Another methodological issue concerns the effect the size of the stakes may have on behaviour. The empirical evidence on this issue generally is that high stakes may slightly affect behaviour, but frequently the effects are not even strong enough to be significant [c.f. 225 the overview given by Camerer (2003)]. In particular, quite a number of experiments have been conducted in which the average payoff was close to a monthly or even annual salary of the participants (e.g. Slonim and Roth, 1998). Typically, even in these experiments subjects exhibit very similar patterns of behaviour as in analogue normal stakes experiments with average payoffs close to the opportunity cost of participation, i.e. close 230 to the average expected hourly wage of the group. 3. Results 3.1 Outcomes without race or income information In the original trust game of Berg et al. (1995) subjects were not provided with any socioeconomic information on their counterparts. Nevertheless, it is clear that the subjects had 235 some general notion of the cultural environment in which their partnerships lay. All subjects in that study were university students in the USA. Our subject pool is similar, because all our subjects are university students in South Africa. Clearly, a basic assessment of the general level of trust and trustworthiness exhibited by our subjects is necessary to ensure comparability of our results concerning the main treatment effects (i.e. the effect of 240 socio-economic information on behaviour). Hence, we conducted the no information treatment, which provides us with such a general benchmark, because it elicits behaviour with the same amount of socio-economic information as was given in the original study. In other words, by comparing the results of our no information treatment to the results of Berg et al. (1995), we can examine in which way trust and trustworthiness in South African 245 student communities differs from the US students behaviour, when behaviour in both cases is elicited in the absence of socio-economic discrimination effects. Table 2 presents summary statistics on the original study by Berg et al. (1995) and our two treatments. The table displays the number of independent observations, the initial endowment size, the observed proportion of senders transferring zero, the average 250 investment ratio (i.e. the ratio of the sent amount to the endowment), and the average return ratio (i.e. the ratio of the amount returned to the initial endowment plus received transfer). It is striking how close the values of the three observational variables are when we compare our no information data to the original data. In fact, statistical tests confirm that there is no difference between the behaviour of US and South African subjects in the trust 255 game. 1 Interestingly, this result also stands if we compare the behaviour of the subjects in each of the socio-economic groups of the no information treatment separately. Table 3 reports the investment ratio (both actual and anticipated) as well as the return ratio (both actual and anticipated) for the sub-samples in the no information treatment. 2 Trusting and 1 We use the Mann Whitney U-test to check for location differences between the Berg et al. (1995) data and our no information data. We find significant differences (not even on a 20%, one-tailed level) neither in the portion of senders sending zero, nor in the investment ratio, nor in the return ratio. 2 The BH sub-sample is left out of this analysis, due to the very small number of observations we have.

8 8 of 22 D. Haile et al. Table 2. Comparison of behaviour of subjects between data from Berg et al. (1995) and South Africa Berg et al. (1995) South Africa a No information With information Independent observations Initial endowment size US$10.00 ZAF$20.00 ZAF$20.00 Proportion of first players who sent zero Investment ratio (ratio of investment to endowment) Return ratio (ratio of return to amount available) a In Berg et al. (1995), second players make responses only when senders invest more than zero while in South African experiment subjects continue to play as we used the strategy method. 260 reciprocating behaviour in none of the sub-sample groups of the no information treatment is statistically different from the behaviour of the Berg et al. (1995) subjects. Furthermore, none of the across sub-sample comparisons (e.g. BL versus WL, BL versus WH etc.) reveals a significant difference in behaviour. Thus, despite the fact that South African society is rather heterogeneous, it seems that the general level of trust and 265 trustworthiness (as measured by the trust game) is similar to the level found in more homogenous societies (Camerer, 2003) when discrimination based on race or income information is not possible. 3.2 Aggregate outcomes with race and income information The last column of Table 2 displays the average aggregate outcomes in the information 270 treatment, in which subjects were given socio-economic information on their counterparts. Despite the fact that there are a few more investors sending 0, and that the average aggregate investment is slightly lower in the information than in the no information treatment, we do not observe either strong or significant differences when comparing our treatments to one another, nor when comparing them to the results of Berg et al. (1995). Even a closer 275 look at the relationship between the invested amount and the return ratio does not reveal any behavioural differences on the aggregate level. As displayed by Figure 1, the way the Table 3. Average percentages of available amounts in the no information treatment Socio-economic group BL WL WH Investment ratio Anticipated investment ratio Return ratio Anticipated return ratio BL, black on low (below average) income; WL, white on low income; WH, white on high income. Note that income categories are based on subject s own selfassessment. The BH sub-sample is left out of this analysis, due to the very small number of observations we have

9 Cross-racial envy and underinvestment 9 of Return ratio Return ratio Amounts available in South African Rand No Information Amounts available in South African Rand With Information Fig. 1. Aggregate return ratio at different investment levels. average return ratio increases with the investment level seems to be very similar both with and without socio-economic information. 3.3 Group specific investment decisions with race and income information 280 While the effect of race and income information seems rather small in the aggregate, we can use our detailed data to analyse whether differences exist between the socio-economic groups. Figure 2 shows the average investment ratio exhibited by the subjects in each of the four socio-economic sub-samples (BL, BH, WL and WH) of the information treatment when facing a receiver from their own or from each of the other groups. 1. To facilitate the 285 comparisons, the average investment ratios are shown as deviations from the average investment ratio in the no information treatment (i.e. 0.55). We use the behaviour in the no information treatment as a benchmark, because it cannot be biased by any deliberate discrimination that specifically targets the socio-economic group of the counterpart. Furthermore, since we have established that the behaviour in our no information 290 treatment is indistinguishable from the trust game behaviour observed in completely different cultural settings, the no information benchmark seems to exhibit a certain degree of universality. The leftmost section of Figure 2 displays the average investment ratios chosen by BL subjects in each of their four possible partnerships. Although all four averages lie below the 295 benchmark of the no information treatment, only investment ratios in partnerships with WH subject are, on average, significantly below the benchmark. 2 The third section of Figure 2 shows that WL subjects also tend to invest less when they have socio-economic information on their counterpart than when they do not. Exactly as in the case of the BL subjects, a cross-racial relationship specifies the only partnership in which the investments 300 of the WL subjects are significantly lower than in the no information benchmark. The average investment ratio of the WL subjects in informed partnerships with BH subjects is just above 17%, which is not only dramatically and significantly less than the average 60% 1 Due to a lack of observations we are not able to present any meaningful mutual relationship between BH subjects and WL and BH subjects, respectively. 2 We compare the group s decisions with the overall averages (benchmark case). It would not change our results if comparison were made with group averages. Moreover, we do not find any statistically significant differences in the behaviour of the BL subjects when comparing locations, i.e. Potchefstroom with Mafikeng.

10 10 of 22 D. Haile et al. Investment Investing subjects Black Low (BL) Black High (BH) White Low (WL) White High (WH) a b BL BH WL WH BL WH BL BH WL WH BL BH WL WH Receiving subjects Fig. 2. Average investment ratio. The bars represent the average investment ratio that was exhibited by investors in each socio-economic group (sub-title on top) in partnerships with receivers of each socioeconomic group (indicated on the x-axis). (a) Significantly lower investment ratio in partnerships with WH than in the no information benchmark (at 5%, one-tailed). (b) Significantly lower investment ratio in partnerships with BL than with WH (at 1%, one-tailed). (c) Significantly lower investment ratio in partnerships with BH than in the no information benchmark (at 1%, one-tailed). (d) Significantly lower investment ratio in partnerships with BH than with WL, BL, and WH (at 1%, 1% and 5%, one-tailed, correspondingly). c, d investment ratio of WL subjects in the no information treatment, but also significantly less than any of their average investment ratios in partnerships with any of the other three 305 groups (47.5%, 55.7%, and 52% for BL, WL and WH, respectively). The second and fourth sections of Figure 2 show that, while WH subjects, on average, do not differentiate their investments by socio-economic categories (i.e. there are no significant effects of socio-economic information on investment behaviour), the BH subjects do. The average investment of BH subjects in partnerships with BL subjects is 310 significantly lower than their average investment in partnerships with WH subjects. The average investment ratio of BH in BL partnerships (25%) is also substantially below the BH average investment ratio in the no information benchmark (55%). The lack of statistical significance in this comparison is most probably due to the relatively small number of observations with BH subjects. 315 The fact that subjects differentiate their investments according to the socio-economic characteristics of their counterpart can be based either on a preference for discrimination or on distrust. Distrust towards a certain other group may not be justified, i.e. that group may actually be trustworthy on average, but thought to be the contrary, perhaps due to widespread prejudices in the investor group. But, if the distrust is actually justified, because 320 the average return by partners from the specific socio-economic group is below the return by others, then the low investment may be solely driven by economic incentives and completely free of any preference for discrimination. Figure 3 shows the average return ratio that subjects expected from each of the groups of counterparts. Note that the BL subjects expected almost equal levels of return from all 325 groups. This is important, because it shows that investing very little in partnerships with WH subjects is not due to a low-return expectation, but due to a conscious act of discrimination that is probably based on envy. Note, furthermore, that the observed envy seems to be purely cross-racial, because the BL subjects expectations concerning, and behaviour towards, the rich in their own ethnic group is statistically indistinguishable from 330 the no information benchmark.

11 Anticipated return ratio Black Low (BL) Cross-racial envy and underinvestment 11 of 22 Black High (BH) Investing subjects a White Low (WL) b Returning Subjects c White High (WH) BL BH WL WH BL WH BL BH WL WH BL BH WL WH Fig. 3. Average anticipated return ratio. The bars represent the average return ratio that was expected by investors of each socio-economic group (sub-titles on top) in partnerships with receivers of each socio-economic group (indicated on the x-axis). (a) Significantly lower return ratio expected in partnerships with BL than with WH (at 5%, one-tailed). (b) Significantly lower return ratio expected in partnerships with BH than with WH (at 1%, one-tailed). (c) Significantly lower return ratio expected in partnerships with BL than with BH (at 5%, one-tailed). For the WL subjects things are slightly different. Just as for the BL subjects, WL subjects show cross-racial envy by investing significantly less only in partnerships with BH subjects. The slight difference is that the WL subjects also expect significantly smaller return ratios from the BH subjects than from the WH subjects. Note, however, that this difference is 335 mainly due to the overly optimistic view of the WL subjects on the behaviour of the rich in their own ethnic group. Compared to the benchmark of no information, their return expectations are not significantly different. Summarising, we find discrimination based on cross-racial envy, since both low income type investors (BL and WL) discriminate towards the high income type receivers of the 340 other ethnic group (WH and BH, respectively). In addition to the cross-racial envy effect, we observe that BH subjects discriminate against the poor in their own ethnic group, by investing very little in those partnerships, even though they expect returns from BL subjects to be no different than from any other group. Finally, we also observe mildly charitable behaviour of the WH subjects, who invest substantial amounts in partnerships 345 with BL subjects, even though they expect less to be returned to them by the BL subjects than by any other group. 3.4 Group specific return decisions with race and income information Figure 4 indicates the average return ratio chosen by the subjects of each socio-economic group in their partnerships with subjects of different socio-economic groups. None of the 350 average return ratios is significantly different from the average return ratio observed in the no information treatment. Furthermore, there is only a single case in which the subjects of one group significantly differentiate their return responses on the basis of the socioeconomic characteristics. BL subjects exhibit lower return ratios in partnerships with WH subjects than with WL subjects. This seems to correspond to the cross-racial envy effect 355 that we also observe concerning the investment ratio of the BL subjects. It seems that WH subjects are generally treated somewhat worse by the BL subjects. Note first that this behaviour must be driven by some non-monetary motivation, because the BL subjects

12 12 of 22 D. Haile et al Returning subjects Black Low (BL) Black High (BH) White Low (WL) White High (WH) Return ratio a BL BH WL WH BL WH BL BH WL WH BL BH WL WH Receiving subjects Fig. 4. Average return ratio. The bars represent the average return ratio that was exhibited by receivers in each socio-economic group (sub-title on top) in partnerships with investors of each socioeconomic group (indicated on the x-axis). (a) Significantly lower return ratio in partnerships with WH than with WL (at 5%, one-tailed). invest less in partnerships with WH subjects even though they do not expect lower returns. Note also that the adverse treatment of WH subjects by BL subjects cannot be a purely 360 racial differentiation effect, since we observe a (insignificantly) higher average return ratio of the BL subjects in partnerships with WL subjects than in any partnership with black subjects. Comparing the expressed beliefs of investors and the observed return behaviour, we generally find no significant differences. Hence, expectations and behaviour are pretty 365 well-aligned, perhaps with the notable exception of the white subjects expectations of the black, low-income subjects return behaviour. Although the differences are neither extreme nor significant, it seems that the white subjects, particularly the WH subjects, underestimate the trustworthiness of the BL subjects. Finally, note that the slightly charitable behaviour of WH subjects as investors is 370 echoed in the fact that they, on average, return more to BL subjects than to subjects from any other group. Although the differences in return ratios are not statistically significant, they seem to underline a generally charitable attitude in the group of white, high-income subjects. Figure 5 displays the average investment ratios that were expected in each type of 375 partnership by the receiving subjects in each of the socio-economic groups. As in the previous figures, the average investment ratio expected in the no information treatment is used as a benchmark. In general, the expressed expectations are not significantly distinguishable from the benchmark. Nevertheless, two interesting observation can be made. First, in many cases where an above benchmark investment ratio was expected, the 380 actual investment ratio was below zero and vice versa. In other words, the expectations are not always well aligned with the actual behaviour. Second, the only significant effects observed relate to the expectations of white subjects concerning the investment ratios of BH and WL subjects. All white subjects expect too low investment ratios by BH subjects and too high investment ratios by the WL subjects, when compared with the actual 385 investment behaviour. 3.5 Payoff consequences In the analysis so far, we focused on detecting differential behaviour and expectations. When subjects choices were in conflict with their expectations of monetary income, we

13 Anticipated investment Black Low (BL) Cross-racial envy and underinvestment 13 of 22 Black High (BH) Returning subjects White Low (WL) b BL BH WL WH BL WH BL BH WL WH BL BH WL WH Investing subjects a White High (WH) c Fig. 5. Average anticipated investment ratio. The bars represent the average investment ratio that was expected by receivers in each socio-economic group (sub-title on top) in partnerships with investors of each socio-economic group (indicated on the x-axis). (a) Significantly lower investment ratio expected in partnerships with BH than with WL (at 1%, one-tailed). (b) Significantly lower investment ratio expected in partnerships with WH than with WL (at 5%, one-tailed). (c) Significantly lower investment ratio expected in partnerships with BH than with WL (at 1%, one-tailed). could localise a preference for differential treatment for which a payoff disadvantage was 390 taken into account. In this section we pursue the question how the observed behaviour translates into payoffs for the different subject types. Since we have elicited strategies from our subjects, we can create a more complete picture of the distribution of payoffs by calculating the average payoff each subject would have had if we had matched him/her to every possible counterpart from the corresponding socio-economic group. The top two 395 panels in Figure 6 show the averages of these population payoffs for the investors and the receivers, correspondingly. The lowest panel displays the average income of both roles in each of the socio-economic groups. The no information benchmark is once again provided to allow a visual assessment of the effect of socio-economic information on the payoffs achieved in the game. 400 The general picture that emerges from Figure 6 is that socio-economic information has an adverse effect on the behaviour in partnerships, leading to negative payoff consequences. This holds in particular for BL subjects who are on the losing side in all but one of the possible partnerships. Only BL subjects in partnership with WH subjects earn substantially more than in the no information benchmark. This 405 is mainly due to the fact that WH subjects invest significantly more in partnerships with a BL receiver than in the no information benchmark, although they receive significantly less from the BL subjects. While WH subjects are acting more generously than they would without information, the BL subjects are behaving less generously than they would without information. It is not surprising that the strongest payoff effects 410 of the socio-economic information are present in this specific relationship, in which subjects exhibit preferences for differential treatment that are not based on monetary incentives. 4. Determinants of experimental decisions In this section, we report a series of regression analyses that help to quantify the observed 415 effects of the socio-economic information given to the subjects. Additionally, the

14 14 of 22 D. Haile et al. South African Rand South African Rand Average Payoff as Investors Black Low Black High (BH) White Low (WL) White High (WH) a* a** a*** BL BH WL WH BL WH BL BH WL WH BL BH WL WH Receivers Black Low (BL) Black High (BH) White Low (WL) White High (WH) a** a*** a* a** a*** Average Payoff as Receivers BL BH WL WH BL WH BL BH WL WH BL BH WL WH Investors a*** South African Rand Average Payoff of Players in any Role Black Low (BL) Black High (BH) White Low (WL) White High (WH) a*** a** a** BL BH WL WH BL WH BL BH WL WH BL BH WL WH Pairs Fig. 6. Average payoffs. The bars represent the average payoff of the corresponding players in each socio-economic group (sub-title on top) in partnerships with counterparts of each socio-economic group (indicated on the x-axis). For the WL subjects linked to BH subjects we have no observations on the latter. In this case, therefore, we determined the WL payoffs by drawing from observations from a pilot. Significant at *10% level, one-tailed, **5% level, one-tailed and ***1% level, one-tailed, respectively. a*** regressions are used to check for correlations of the observed behaviour to the questionnaire answers provided by the subjects. We can confirm that low-income subjects send significantly less than other subjects if they are linked to high-income subjects of the other race. Moreover, we show that the questionnaire responses do not provide reliable 420 forecasts on subjects behaviour. First, the regressions explaining the investment ratio are reported and then the regressions explaining the return ratio.

15 Table 4. Double-censored Tobit estimates on the investment ratio 4.1 Investment ratio Constant (0.111)*** (0.109)*** (0.181)*** (0.176) Male (0.071) (0.069) (0.074) (0.063) Low income (0.082)** (0.086) (0.091) (0.078) White (0.078) (0.077) (0.084) (0.070) Income-hetro (0.098) (0.096) (0.097) (0.084) Race-hetro (0.104) (0.101) (0.102) (0.088) Social distance (0.143) (0.194) (0.195) (0.169) Income*Soc (0.184)*** (0.189)*** (0.161)*** Perceptions (0.041) (0.036) Opportunity (0.074) (0.062) Education (0.084) (0.071) Trust index (0.051) (0.044) Expected return ratio (0.161) Expected investment ratio (0.106)*** S (0.031) (0.030) (0.030) (0.025) Log likelihood Wald Test (x 2 ) Observations Numbers in parentheses are the estimated standard errors. **Significant at 5% level; ***significant at 1% level. Cross-racial envy and underinvestment 15 of 22 We used a double-censored Tobit regression with the investment ratio as the dependent variable. The results are summarised in Table 4. The variable names are self-explanatory. 425 (See Appendix Table A.1 for the definitions of variables that are reported.) Column 1 contains the coefficient estimates for the regression in which only the basic characteristics of the sender and the receiver are included. None of the coefficients are significant. In particular, not even the dummy variable social distance, which is equal to one when both the race and the income levels of the matched individuals are different, has 430 significant explanatory power for the observed variations in the chosen investment ratios. This may seem surprising on first sight, but is intuitively clear when we take into consideration that the observed behaviour towards subjects from another race and income group is asymmetric, since the low income subjects hold back investments in partnerships with high income subjects from the other race, but the opposite is not true. In column 2, we 435 introduce a dummy variable called income*soc, which is equal to one when the sender has a low income and is matched with a subject of both a different race and a different income level. As expected, the coefficient of this variable is highly significant, confirming our experimental results. In column 3, questionnaire items measuring subjects perceptions of equity and fairness 440 are included. None of the coefficients are significant. Including trust, measured by means of the GSS trust question as an explanatory variable, does not contribute to explaining the investment ratio. 1 Finally, in column 4, subjects expectation of the amount invested and 1 Incidentally, this confirms results by Glaeser et al. (2000), and subsequently others, who show that trust as measured by the trust game does not correspond to the GSS trust measure.

16 16 of 22 D. Haile et al. returned by their partner is included in the regression. The coefficient on the expected investment ratio is positive and significant, suggesting that, in general, subjects own 445 investment behaviour is driven by what they expect their counterparts to invest, but not on what they return. 4.2 Return ratio The estimated coefficients of the return ratio regressions are summarised in Table 5. Single-censored regression is used as every single subject always retained a substantial part 450 of their partner s investment for themself. Since we used the strategy method, we have more than one observation for each respondent. In particular, each respondent had to state how much to return for each of the 11 possible amounts that could be received from the sender. To take the panel character of this dataset into account, we employed the random effects Tobit model. 455 The return ratio is positively correlated to the amount available to the subject, Q. However, since the return ratio increases as a decreasing rate, there is a negative effect of the square of the amount available. The baseline regression also includes the characteristics of both the investor and responder, as reported in column 1 of Table 5. It seems that males return more, while low income participants return less. Neither income nor race 460 heterogeneity, however, seems to play a role in responder s decision on the return. And again, as in the case of the investments, the symmetric cross-effect of income and race ( social distance ) is not significant, while the asymmetric cross-effect ( income*soc ) has a significantly negative effect on the return ratio, thus conforming the negative effect of cross-cultural envy. 465 Adding the questionnaire responses to the regression (column 3), provides significantly negative, but very small effects for the perceptions and trust index variables, which indicate whether the subject perceives inequality as having been generated fairly and, correspondingly, whether the subject generally trusts others. However, since both coefficients switch to positive as soon as we add the expectation on investment and return 470 (in column 4), it seems that the actual effect of these variables cannot be measured very precisely. However, there is a significantly positive effect between the expected return from the partner and one s own return ratio. 5. Concluding remarks We report the results of a series of experimental trust games conducted in South Africa 475 focusing on the effects of racial and income inequality on cooperation in partnerships. We vary the amount of socio-economic information available to the subjects about their counterparts in order to assess the effect of inequality between the partners. In the control treatment, in which no such information is provided, we observe no significant differences in the behaviour across races and income groups. In fact, despite the extreme heterogeneity 480 of South African society, we find that the general level of trust and trustworthiness observed in the control treatment is very similar to that which is observed in more homogenous societies. When socio-economic information on their counterparts is provided to the subjects, individual trust behaviour is affected significantly. While we neither observe simple racial 485 nor simple income-based discrimination, we do observe that the low income subjects from both racial groups invest significantly less in partnerships with the high income subjects of

How Much Should We Trust the World Values Survey Trust Question?

How Much Should We Trust the World Values Survey Trust Question? How Much Should We Trust the World Values Survey Trust Question? Noel D. Johnson * Department of Economics George Mason University Alexandra Mislin Kogod School of Business, American University Abstract

More information

Today s lecture. A thought experiment. Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness. Overview readings: Fehr and Fischbacher (2002) Sobel (2005)

Today s lecture. A thought experiment. Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness. Overview readings: Fehr and Fischbacher (2002) Sobel (2005) Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness Are we perfectly selfish? If not, does it affect economic analysis? How to take it into account? Overview readings: Fehr and Fischbacher (2002) Sobel (2005) Today

More information

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION Supplementary Statistics and Results This file contains supplementary statistical information and a discussion of the interpretation of the belief effect on the basis of additional data. We also present

More information

Online Appendix A. A1 Ability

Online Appendix A. A1 Ability Online Appendix A A1 Ability To exclude the possibility of a gender difference in ability in our sample, we conducted a betweenparticipants test in which we measured ability by asking participants to engage

More information

How to identify trust and reciprocity

How to identify trust and reciprocity Games and Economic Behavior 46 (2004) 260 281 www.elsevier.com/locate/geb How to identify trust and reciprocity JamesC.Cox Department of Economics, 401 McClelland Hall, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ

More information

The Game Prisoners Really Play: Preference Elicitation and the Impact of Communication

The Game Prisoners Really Play: Preference Elicitation and the Impact of Communication The Game Prisoners Really Play: Preference Elicitation and the Impact of Communication Michael Kosfeld University of Zurich Ernst Fehr University of Zurich October 10, 2003 Unfinished version: Please do

More information

DIFFERENCES IN THE ECONOMIC DECISIONS OF MEN AND WOMEN: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE*

DIFFERENCES IN THE ECONOMIC DECISIONS OF MEN AND WOMEN: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE* DIFFERENCES IN THE ECONOMIC DECISIONS OF MEN AND WOMEN: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE* Catherine C. Eckel Department of Economics Virginia Tech Blacksburg, VA 24061-0316 Philip J. Grossman Department of Economics

More information

Trust and Reciprocity among Urban Slum Dwellers:

Trust and Reciprocity among Urban Slum Dwellers: Trust and Reciprocity among Urban Slum Dwellers: Experimental Findings from a Trust Game in Hyderabad Bibhu P. Nayak Tata Institute of Social Sciences (TISS) Hyderabad Introduction The economic payoff

More information

The Dynamic Interplay of Inequality and Trust - An Experimental Study

The Dynamic Interplay of Inequality and Trust - An Experimental Study 08-026 The Dynamic Interplay of Inequality and Trust - An Experimental Study Ben Greiner Axel Ockenfels Peter Werner Copyright 2007 by Ben Greiner, Axel Ockenfels, and Peter Werner Working papers are in

More information

Koji Kotani International University of Japan. Abstract

Koji Kotani International University of Japan. Abstract Further investigations of framing effects on cooperative choices in a provision point mechanism Koji Kotani International University of Japan Shunsuke Managi Yokohama National University Kenta Tanaka Yokohama

More information

Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness

Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness Are we perfectly selfish and self-centered? If not, does it affect economic analysis? How to take it into account? Focus: Descriptive analysis Examples Will monitoring

More information

Veronika Grimm, Friederike Mengel. Let me sleep on it: Delay reduces rejection rates in Ultimatum Games RM/10/017

Veronika Grimm, Friederike Mengel. Let me sleep on it: Delay reduces rejection rates in Ultimatum Games RM/10/017 Veronika Grimm, Friederike Mengel Let me sleep on it: Delay reduces rejection rates in Ultimatum Games RM/10/017 Let me sleep on it: Delay reduces rejection rates in Ultimatum Games Veronika Grimm Friederike

More information

GENDER SELECTION DISCRIMINATION: EVIDENCE FROM A TRUST GAME* Robert Slonim Case Western Reserve University. September 7 th, 2004

GENDER SELECTION DISCRIMINATION: EVIDENCE FROM A TRUST GAME* Robert Slonim Case Western Reserve University. September 7 th, 2004 GENDER SELECTION DISCRIMINATION: EVIDENCE FROM A TRUST GAME* Robert Slonim Case Western Reserve University September 7 th, 2004 Abstract: Although discrimination remains prevalent, the reasons for its

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE COLLEGE OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CANTERBURY CHRISTCHURCH, NEW ZEALAND

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE COLLEGE OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CANTERBURY CHRISTCHURCH, NEW ZEALAND DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE COLLEGE OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CANTERBURY CHRISTCHURCH, NEW ZEALAND Comment on Promises and Partnership Cary Deck, Maroš Servátka, and Steven Tucker

More information

UNDERSTANDING TRUST*

UNDERSTANDING TRUST* The Economic Journal, 123 (December), 1313 1332. Doi: 10.1111/ecoj.12036 2013 The Author(s). The Economic Journal 2013 Royal Economic Society. Published by John Wiley & Sons, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford

More information

Identity, Homophily and In-Group Bias: Experimental Evidence

Identity, Homophily and In-Group Bias: Experimental Evidence Identity, Homophily and In-Group Bias: Experimental Evidence Friederike Mengel & Sergio Currarini Univeersity of Nottingham Universita Ca Foscari and FEEM, Venice FEEM, March 2012 In-Group Bias Experimental

More information

Leadership with Individual Rewards and Punishments

Leadership with Individual Rewards and Punishments MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Leadership with Individual Rewards and Punishments Özgür Gürerk and Thomas Lauer and Martin Scheuermann RWTH Aachen University, University of Cologne 17. July 2015 Online

More information

Investigating the well-being of rural women in South Africa

Investigating the well-being of rural women in South Africa Investigating the well-being of rural women in South Africa Daniela Casale and Dorrit Posel abstract In this Focus piece we explore differences in the well-being of men and women in rural and urban areas.

More information

Masculinity and lying

Masculinity and lying Masculinity and lying Marc Vorsatz UNED Santiago Sanchez-Pages University of Barcelona Enrique Turiegano Universidad Autónoma de Madrid March 10, 2016 Abstract Dishonesty in communication has important

More information

Version No. 7 Date: July Please send comments or suggestions on this glossary to

Version No. 7 Date: July Please send comments or suggestions on this glossary to Impact Evaluation Glossary Version No. 7 Date: July 2012 Please send comments or suggestions on this glossary to 3ie@3ieimpact.org. Recommended citation: 3ie (2012) 3ie impact evaluation glossary. International

More information

Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization

Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 68 (2008) 466 476 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Trust

More information

Playing the Trust Game with Other People s Money *

Playing the Trust Game with Other People s Money * Playing the Trust Game with Other People s Money * Ola Kvaløy ** and Miguel Luzuriaga *** November, 2012 Abstract: We experimentally investigate to what extent people trust and honor trust when they are

More information

Group Composition and Cooperation

Group Composition and Cooperation Group Composition and Cooperation Alexander Smith May 15, 2009 Abstract This paper presents an experiment designed to measure how heterogeneous identity affects contributions in a voluntary contribution

More information

EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS INTRODUCTION. Ernesto Reuben

EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS INTRODUCTION. Ernesto Reuben EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS INTRODUCTION Ernesto Reuben WHAT IS EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS? 2 WHAT IS AN ECONOMICS EXPERIMENT? A method of collecting data in controlled environments with the purpose of furthering

More information

Positive reciprocity and intentions in trust games

Positive reciprocity and intentions in trust games Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization Vol. 52 (2003) 267 275 Positive reciprocity and intentions in trust games Kevin A. McCabe a, Mary L. Rigdon b,, Vernon L. Smith a a Interdisciplinary Center

More information

THE DETERMINANTS OF TRUSTING AND RECIPROCAL BEHAVIOUR: EVIDENCE FROM AN INTERCULTURAL EXPERIMENT

THE DETERMINANTS OF TRUSTING AND RECIPROCAL BEHAVIOUR: EVIDENCE FROM AN INTERCULTURAL EXPERIMENT JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 71 Volume 33, Number 1, June 2008 THE DETERMINANTS OF TRUSTING AND RECIPROCAL BEHAVIOUR: EVIDENCE FROM AN INTERCULTURAL EXPERIMENT CSONGOR CSUKÁS, PAULO FRACALANZA, TAMÁS

More information

ExpEc I. Preliminaries

ExpEc I. Preliminaries ExpEc I. Preliminaries Giovanni Ponti Università di Ferrara Facoltà di Giurisprudenza LUISS Guido Carli LAboratory for Theoretical and EXperimental Economics Universidad de Alicante Roma, 7/6/2010 h t

More information

Charitable Giving as a Gift Exchange: Evidence from a Field Experiment

Charitable Giving as a Gift Exchange: Evidence from a Field Experiment DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 1148 Charitable Giving as a Gift Exchange: Evidence from a Field Experiment Armin Falk May 2004 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor

More information

The Role of Gender and Race in Cooperation and Trust: Experimental Examination of Identity Based Strategic Interaction

The Role of Gender and Race in Cooperation and Trust: Experimental Examination of Identity Based Strategic Interaction The Role of and Race in Cooperation and Trust: Experimental Examination of Identity Based Strategic Interaction Vincent Leah-Martin * University of California, San Diego ABSTRACT: Recent work in behavioral

More information

Gender Effects in Private Value Auctions. John C. Ham Department of Economics, University of Southern California and IZA. and

Gender Effects in Private Value Auctions. John C. Ham Department of Economics, University of Southern California and IZA. and Gender Effects in Private Value Auctions 2/1/05 Revised 3/3/06 John C. Ham Department of Economics, University of Southern California and IZA and John H. Kagel** Department of Economics, The Ohio State

More information

UNIVERSITÀ DEGLI STUDI DI SIENA QUADERNI DEL DIPARTIMENTO DI ECONOMIA POLITICA E STATISTICA. Luigi Luini Annamaria Nese Patrizia Sbriglia

UNIVERSITÀ DEGLI STUDI DI SIENA QUADERNI DEL DIPARTIMENTO DI ECONOMIA POLITICA E STATISTICA. Luigi Luini Annamaria Nese Patrizia Sbriglia UNIVERSITÀ DEGLI STUDI DI SIENA QUADERNI DEL DIPARTIMENTO DI ECONOMIA POLITICA E STATISTICA Luigi Luini Annamaria Nese Patrizia Sbriglia Social Influence in Trustors Neighborhoods n. 626 Novembre 2011

More information

Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game

Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game Ivaylo Vlaev (ivaylo.vlaev@psy.ox.ac.uk) Department of Experimental Psychology, University of Oxford, Oxford, OX1

More information

CHAPTER 4 RESULTS. In this chapter the results of the empirical research are reported and discussed in the following order:

CHAPTER 4 RESULTS. In this chapter the results of the empirical research are reported and discussed in the following order: 71 CHAPTER 4 RESULTS 4.1 INTRODUCTION In this chapter the results of the empirical research are reported and discussed in the following order: (1) Descriptive statistics of the sample; the extraneous variables;

More information

Decomposing Trust and Trustworthiness

Decomposing Trust and Trustworthiness 1 Decomposing Trust and Trustworthiness Nava Ashraf, Iris Bohnet and Nikita Piankov What motivates people to trust and be trustworthy? Is trust solely calculative, based on the expectation of trustworthiness,

More information

Belief Formation in a Signalling Game without Common Prior: An Experiment

Belief Formation in a Signalling Game without Common Prior: An Experiment Belief Formation in a Signalling Game without Common Prior: An Experiment Alex Possajennikov University of Nottingham February 2012 Abstract Using belief elicitation, the paper investigates the formation

More information

Women s Empowerment Framework: Adapted for Zimbabwe Case Study

Women s Empowerment Framework: Adapted for Zimbabwe Case Study Women s Empowerment Framework: Adapted for Zimbabwe Case Study Gender Analysis SOWK Advanced Modules 1 Alysia Wright, MSW University of Calgary UID 10101638 Women s Empowerment Framework Introduction Gender

More information

How financial incentives and cognitive abilities. affect task performance in laboratory settings: an illustration

How financial incentives and cognitive abilities. affect task performance in laboratory settings: an illustration How financial incentives and cognitive abilities affect task performance in laboratory settings: an illustration Ondrej Rydval, Andreas Ortmann CERGE-EI, Prague, Czech Republic April 2004 Abstract Drawing

More information

CHAPTER 14 ORAL HEALTH AND ORAL CARE IN ADULTS

CHAPTER 14 ORAL HEALTH AND ORAL CARE IN ADULTS CHAPTER 14 ORAL HEALTH AND ORAL CARE IN ADULTS 14.1 Introduction Oral diseases are widespread in South Africa and affect large numbers of people in terms of pain, tooth loss, disfigurement, loss of function

More information

Explaining Bargaining Impasse: The Role of Self-Serving Biases

Explaining Bargaining Impasse: The Role of Self-Serving Biases Explaining Bargaining Impasse: The Role of Self-Serving Biases Linda Babcock and George Loewenstein Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1997 報告人 : 高培儒 20091028 1 1. Introduction Economists, and more specifically

More information

Social Preferences of Young Adults in Japan: The Roles of Age and Gender

Social Preferences of Young Adults in Japan: The Roles of Age and Gender Social Preferences of Young Adults in Japan: The Roles of Age and Gender Akihiro Kawase Faculty of Economics, Toyo University, Japan November 26, 2014 E-mail address: kawase@toyo.jp Postal address: Faculty

More information

THE USE OF MULTIVARIATE ANALYSIS IN DEVELOPMENT THEORY: A CRITIQUE OF THE APPROACH ADOPTED BY ADELMAN AND MORRIS A. C. RAYNER

THE USE OF MULTIVARIATE ANALYSIS IN DEVELOPMENT THEORY: A CRITIQUE OF THE APPROACH ADOPTED BY ADELMAN AND MORRIS A. C. RAYNER THE USE OF MULTIVARIATE ANALYSIS IN DEVELOPMENT THEORY: A CRITIQUE OF THE APPROACH ADOPTED BY ADELMAN AND MORRIS A. C. RAYNER Introduction, 639. Factor analysis, 639. Discriminant analysis, 644. INTRODUCTION

More information

Supplementary Information Appendix for: Prenatal Sex Hormones (2D:4D Digit Ratio) and Social Integration

Supplementary Information Appendix for: Prenatal Sex Hormones (2D:4D Digit Ratio) and Social Integration Supplementary Information Appendix for: Prenatal Sex Hormones (2D:4D Digit Ratio) and Social Integration Jaromír Kovářík*, Pablo Brañas-Garza**, Michael W. Davidson, Dotan A. Haim, Shannon Carcelli, and

More information

good reputation, and less chance to be chosen as potential partners. Fourth, not everyone values a good reputation to the same extent.

good reputation, and less chance to be chosen as potential partners. Fourth, not everyone values a good reputation to the same extent. English Summary 128 English summary English Summary S ocial dilemmas emerge when people experience a conflict between their immediate personal interest and the long-term collective interest of the group

More information

Tilburg University. Publication date: Link to publication

Tilburg University. Publication date: Link to publication Tilburg University Leading by Example? Investment Decisions in a Mixed Sequential-Simultaneous Public Bad Experiment van der Heijden, Eline; Moxnes, E. Publication date: 2003 Link to publication Citation

More information

A Note On the Design of Experiments Involving Public Goods

A Note On the Design of Experiments Involving Public Goods University of Colorado From the SelectedWorks of PHILIP E GRAVES 2009 A Note On the Design of Experiments Involving Public Goods PHILIP E GRAVES, University of Colorado at Boulder Available at: https://works.bepress.com/philip_graves/40/

More information

Lecture 3. QIAO Zhilin ( 乔志林 ) School of Economics & Finance Xi an Jiaotong University

Lecture 3. QIAO Zhilin ( 乔志林 )   School of Economics & Finance Xi an Jiaotong University Lecture 3 QIAO Zhilin ( 乔志林 ).co School of Economics & Finance Xi an Jiaotong University October, 2015 Introduction Ultimatum Game Traditional Economics Fairness is simply a rhetorical term Self-interest

More information

TRUST AND RECIPROCITY AMONG INTERNATIONAL GROUPS: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE FROM AUSTRIA AND JAPAN

TRUST AND RECIPROCITY AMONG INTERNATIONAL GROUPS: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE FROM AUSTRIA AND JAPAN Discussion Paper No. 737 TRUST AND RECIPROCITY AMONG INTERNATIONAL GROUPS: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE FROM AUSTRIA AND JAPAN Kenju Akai and Robert J. Netzer May 2009 Revised August 2010 The Institute of Social

More information

Whom to trust? Choice of partner in a trust game.

Whom to trust? Choice of partner in a trust game. Whom to trust? Choice of partner in a trust game. Catherine C. Eckel* Department of Economics (0316) Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University Rick K. Wilson Department of Political Science Rice

More information

The Voluntary Provision of a Public Good with Binding Multi-Round Commitments

The Voluntary Provision of a Public Good with Binding Multi-Round Commitments September 28, 2005 The Voluntary Provision of a Public Good with Binding Multi-Round Commitments Matthew A. Halloran Department of Economics, Kansas State University, Waters Hall 339A, Manhattan, KS 66506,

More information

Decomposing trust and trustworthiness

Decomposing trust and trustworthiness Exp Econ (2006) 9:193 208 DOI 10.1007/s10683-006-9122-4 Decomposing trust and trustworthiness Nava Ashraf Iris Bohnet Nikita Piankov Received: 1 February 2005 / Revised: 30 November 2005 / Accepted: 14

More information

The Dynamic Interplay of Inequality and Trust - An Experimental Study

The Dynamic Interplay of Inequality and Trust - An Experimental Study The Dynamic Interplay of Inequality and Trust - An Experimental Study Ben Greiner, Axel Ockenfels, and Peter Werner Abstract We study the interplay of inequality and trust in a dynamic growth game, in

More information

Feldexperimente in der Soziologie

Feldexperimente in der Soziologie Feldexperimente in der Soziologie Einführungsveranstaltung 04.02.2016 Seite 1 Content 1. Field Experiments 2. What Do Laboratory Experiments Measuring Social Preferences Reveal about the Real World? Lab

More information

Unlike standard economics, BE is (most of the time) not based on rst principles, but on observed behavior of real people.

Unlike standard economics, BE is (most of the time) not based on rst principles, but on observed behavior of real people. Behavioral Economics Lecture 1. Introduction and the Methodology of Experimental Economics 1. Introduction Characteristica of Behavioral Economics (BE) Unlike standard economics, BE is (most of the time)

More information

Author's personal copy

Author's personal copy Exp Econ DOI 10.1007/s10683-015-9466-8 ORIGINAL PAPER The effects of endowment size and strategy method on third party punishment Jillian Jordan 1 Katherine McAuliffe 1,2 David Rand 1,3,4 Received: 19

More information

Relative standing and subjective well-being in South Africa: The role of perceptions, expectations and income mobility

Relative standing and subjective well-being in South Africa: The role of perceptions, expectations and income mobility Relative standing and subjective well-being in South Africa: The role of perceptions, expectations and income mobility Dorrit Posel and Daniela Casale Working Paper 210 March 2011 Relative standing and

More information

Giving Feedback to Clients

Giving Feedback to Clients Giving Feedback to Clients Teck-Hua Ho and Catherine Yeung 1 April 27, 2013 1 Authors are listed in alphabetical order. We thank the editor, the associate editor, and 3 anonymous reviewers for their helpful

More information

Documentos de Trabajo. An experiment on corruption and gender. María Fernanda Rivas

Documentos de Trabajo. An experiment on corruption and gender. María Fernanda Rivas Documentos de Trabajo An experiment on corruption and gender María Fernanda Rivas Documento No. 08/06 Setiembre, 2006 An experiment on corruption and gender María Fernanda Rivas September 2006 Abstract

More information

Trust and Cooperation: An experimental study*

Trust and Cooperation: An experimental study* Trust and Cooperation: An experimental study* Jeongbin Kim, Louis Putterman, and Xinyi Zhang November, 2016 Abstract: We use a two-phase experimental design to study one mechanism through which high trusting

More information

Fairness and Reciprocity in the Hawk-Dove game

Fairness and Reciprocity in the Hawk-Dove game Fairness and Reciprocity in the Hawk-Dove game Tibor Neugebauer*, Anders Poulsen**, and Arthur Schram*** Abstract We study fairness and reciprocity in a Hawk-Dove game. This allows us to test various models

More information

BRIEF COMMUNICATIONS ARISING

BRIEF COMMUNICATIONS ARISING BRIEF COMMUNICATIONS ARISING Intuition and cooperation reconsidered ARISING FROM D. G. Rand, J. D. Greene & M. A. Nowak Nature 489, 427 430 (2012) Rand et al. 1 reported increased cooperation in social

More information

Whom to trust? Choice of partner in a trust game.

Whom to trust? Choice of partner in a trust game. Eckel and Wilson -- 9/27/00 -- p. 1 Version of 9/26/00 8:14 PM Whom to trust? Choice of partner in a trust game. Catherine C. Eckel* Department of Economics (0316) Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State

More information

Do people behave in experiments as in the field? evidence from donations

Do people behave in experiments as in the field? evidence from donations Exp Econ (2008) 11: 268 281 DOI 10.1007/s10683-007-9192-y Do people behave in experiments as in the field? evidence from donations Matthias Benz Stephan Meier Published online: 15 February 2008 Economic

More information

Gender and Culture: International Experimental Evidence from Trust Games

Gender and Culture: International Experimental Evidence from Trust Games Gender and Culture: International Experimental Evidence from Trust Games By RACHEL CROSON AND NANCY BUCHAN* Gender is rarely included as a factor in economics models. However, recent work in experimental

More information

Appendix: Instructions for Treatment Index B (Human Opponents, With Recommendations)

Appendix: Instructions for Treatment Index B (Human Opponents, With Recommendations) Appendix: Instructions for Treatment Index B (Human Opponents, With Recommendations) This is an experiment in the economics of strategic decision making. Various agencies have provided funds for this research.

More information

GROUP DECISION MAKING IN RISKY ENVIRONMENT ANALYSIS OF GENDER BIAS

GROUP DECISION MAKING IN RISKY ENVIRONMENT ANALYSIS OF GENDER BIAS GROUP DECISION MAKING IN RISKY ENVIRONMENT ANALYSIS OF GENDER BIAS Andrea Vasiľková, Matúš Kubák, Vladimír Gazda, Marek Gróf Abstract Article presents an experimental study of gender bias in group decisions.

More information

An Experimental Comparison of the Fairness Models by Bolton and Ockenfels and by Fehr and Schmidt

An Experimental Comparison of the Fairness Models by Bolton and Ockenfels and by Fehr and Schmidt An Experimental Comparison of the Fairness Models by Bolton and Ockenfels and by Fehr and Schmidt Dirk Engelmann y and Martin Strobel z Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin January 29, 2000 Abstract In this

More information

Conference Paper. Conference Paper. Indaba Hotel and Conference Centre Johannesburg South Africa

Conference Paper. Conference Paper. Indaba Hotel and Conference Centre Johannesburg South Africa Conference Paper Conference Paper R e l a t i v e S t a n d i n g a n d S u b j e c t i v e W e l l - B e i n g i n S o u t h A f r i c a : T h e R o l e o f P e r c e p t i o n s, E x p e c t a t i o

More information

John F. Kennedy School of Government Harvard University Faculty Research Working Papers Series

John F. Kennedy School of Government Harvard University Faculty Research Working Papers Series John F. Kennedy School of Government Harvard University Faculty Research Working Papers Series Is Trust a Bad Investment? Nava Ashraf, Iris Bohnet and Nikita Piankov Nov 2003 RWP03-047 The views expressed

More information

The Impact of Relative Standards on the Propensity to Disclose. Alessandro Acquisti, Leslie K. John, George Loewenstein WEB APPENDIX

The Impact of Relative Standards on the Propensity to Disclose. Alessandro Acquisti, Leslie K. John, George Loewenstein WEB APPENDIX The Impact of Relative Standards on the Propensity to Disclose Alessandro Acquisti, Leslie K. John, George Loewenstein WEB APPENDIX 2 Web Appendix A: Panel data estimation approach As noted in the main

More information

By Olivia Smith and Steven van de Put Third Year, Second Prize

By Olivia Smith and Steven van de Put Third Year, Second Prize Are humans always the rational, self-interested agents that mainstream economics assumes them to be? Discuss, using ideas of reciprocity, altruism and fairness By Olivia Smith and Steven van de Put Third

More information

CeDEx Discussion Paper Series ISSN

CeDEx Discussion Paper Series ISSN Discussion Paper No. 2009 10 Klaus Abbink and Benedikt Herrmann June 2009 The Moral Costs of Nastiness CeDEx Discussion Paper Series ISSN 1749 3293 The Centre for Decision Research and Experimental Economics

More information

An analysis of structural changes in the consumption patterns of beer, wine and spirits applying an alternative methodology

An analysis of structural changes in the consumption patterns of beer, wine and spirits applying an alternative methodology An analysis of structural changes in the consumption patterns of beer, wine and spirits applying an alternative methodology 1. Introduction Jan BENTZEN, Valdemar SMITH Department of Economics and Business

More information

Cooperation in a Prisoners Dilemma with Losses. Results from an Experimental Study.

Cooperation in a Prisoners Dilemma with Losses. Results from an Experimental Study. Cooperation in a Prisoners Dilemma with Losses. Results from an Experimental Study. Roger Berger Institute for Sociology, University of Leipzig and SNF Venice International University 2006 Rational Choice

More information

KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT

KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT KRANNERT SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT Purdue University West Lafayette, Indiana EXPLICIT VERSUS IMPLICIT CONTRACTS FOR DIVIDING THE BENEFITS OF COOPERATION By Marco Casari Timothy N. Cason Paper No. 1270 Date:

More information

ULTIMATUM GAME. An Empirical Evidence. Presented By: SHAHID RAZZAQUE

ULTIMATUM GAME. An Empirical Evidence. Presented By: SHAHID RAZZAQUE 1 ULTIMATUM GAME An Empirical Evidence Presented By: SHAHID RAZZAQUE 2 Difference Between Self-Interest, Preference & Social Preference Preference refers to the choices people make & particularly to tradeoffs

More information

WILL HOMO ECONOMICUS SURVIVE?

WILL HOMO ECONOMICUS SURVIVE? WILL HOMO ECONOMICUS SURVIVE? PHILIPP DOERRENBERG Erasmus Student In this essay, Philipp Doerrenberg highlights recent experimental work that has proven the shaky foundations of the concept of the rational,

More information

Contributions and Beliefs in Liner Public Goods Experiment: Difference between Partners and Strangers Design

Contributions and Beliefs in Liner Public Goods Experiment: Difference between Partners and Strangers Design Working Paper Contributions and Beliefs in Liner Public Goods Experiment: Difference between Partners and Strangers Design Tsuyoshi Nihonsugi 1, 2 1 Research Fellow of the Japan Society for the Promotion

More information

Performance in competitive Environments: Gender differences

Performance in competitive Environments: Gender differences Performance in competitive Environments: Gender differences Uri Gneezy Technion and Chicago Business School Muriel Niederle Harvard University Aldo Rustichini University of Minnesota 1 Gender differences

More information

Aspiration Levels and Educational Choices. An experimental study

Aspiration Levels and Educational Choices. An experimental study Aspiration Levels and Educational Choices An experimental study Lionel Page Louis Levy Garboua Claude Montmarquette October 2006 Westminster Business School, University of Westminster, 35 Marylebone Road,

More information

Journal of Public Economics

Journal of Public Economics Journal of Public Economics 95 (2011) 372 394 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Public Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jpube Do fairness and race matter in generosity?

More information

Verbal and behavioural indicators of trust: How well are they associated? Nigel Harvey University College London. Harvey Toulouse October 2009

Verbal and behavioural indicators of trust: How well are they associated? Nigel Harvey University College London. Harvey Toulouse October 2009 Verbal and behavioural indicators of trust: How well are they associated? Nigel Harvey University College London Outline Definitions of trust Some research issues for psychologists Ways of studying trust

More information

Physician-Patient Race-Match & Patient Outcomes

Physician-Patient Race-Match & Patient Outcomes Physician-Patient Race-Match & Patient Outcomes Andrew Hill (Montana State University) Daniel Jones (University of Pittsburgh, GSPIA) Lindsey Woodworth (University of South Carolina) ASSA 2019 Two motivating

More information

Behavioral Game Theory

Behavioral Game Theory School of Computer Science, McGill University March 4, 2011 1 2 3 4 5 Outline Nash equilibria One-shot games 1 2 3 4 5 I Nash equilibria One-shot games Definition: A study of actual individual s behaviors

More information

THE ROLE OF EXPECTATIONS IN THE PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS UNDER THE INFLUENCE OF SOCIAL IDENTITY

THE ROLE OF EXPECTATIONS IN THE PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS UNDER THE INFLUENCE OF SOCIAL IDENTITY Number 201 March 2014 THE ROLE OF EXPECTATIONS IN THE PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS UNDER THE INFLUENCE OF SOCIAL IDENTITY Matthias Lankau, Marianna Bicskei, Kilian Bizer ISSN: 1439-2305 THE ROLE OF EXPECTATIONS

More information

Gift-Exchange in the Field

Gift-Exchange in the Field Gift-Exchange in the Field Armin Falk * University of Bonn, IZA, CEPR, CESifo, DIW Berlin This version: January 2007 Abstract. This study reports evidence from a field experiment that was conducted to

More information

Supporting Information

Supporting Information Supporting Information Burton-Chellew and West 10.1073/pnas.1210960110 SI Results Fig. S4 A and B shows the percentage of free riders and cooperators over time for each treatment. Although Fig. S4A shows

More information

Behavioral Game Theory

Behavioral Game Theory Outline (September 3, 2007) Outline (September 3, 2007) Introduction Outline (September 3, 2007) Introduction Examples of laboratory experiments Outline (September 3, 2007) Introduction Examples of laboratory

More information

HERO. Rational addiction theory a survey of opinions UNIVERSITY OF OSLO HEALTH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PROGRAMME. Working paper 2008: 7

HERO. Rational addiction theory a survey of opinions UNIVERSITY OF OSLO HEALTH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PROGRAMME. Working paper 2008: 7 Rational addiction theory a survey of opinions Hans Olav Melberg Institute of Health Management and Health Economics UNIVERSITY OF OSLO HEALTH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PROGRAMME Working paper 2008: 7 HERO Rational

More information

Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization

Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 85 (2013) 20 34 Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization j our nal ho me p age: www.elsevier.com/locate/jebo

More information

Emanuela Carbonara. 31 January University of Bologna - Department of Economics

Emanuela Carbonara. 31 January University of Bologna - Department of Economics Game Theory, Behavior and The Law - I A brief introduction to game theory. Rules of the game and equilibrium concepts. Behavioral Games: Ultimatum and Dictator Games. Entitlement and Framing effects. Emanuela

More information

MEA DISCUSSION PAPERS

MEA DISCUSSION PAPERS Inference Problems under a Special Form of Heteroskedasticity Helmut Farbmacher, Heinrich Kögel 03-2015 MEA DISCUSSION PAPERS mea Amalienstr. 33_D-80799 Munich_Phone+49 89 38602-355_Fax +49 89 38602-390_www.mea.mpisoc.mpg.de

More information

Findings from lab experiments in urban and rural Uganda

Findings from lab experiments in urban and rural Uganda Gender, context and competition: Findings from lab experiments in urban and rural Uganda Kjetil Bjorvatn a *, Ranveig Falch b, Ulrikke Hernæs c abc Department of Economics, NHH Norwegian School of Economics,

More information

Chapter 12. The One- Sample

Chapter 12. The One- Sample Chapter 12 The One- Sample z-test Objective We are going to learn to make decisions about a population parameter based on sample information. Lesson 12.1. Testing a Two- Tailed Hypothesis Example 1: Let's

More information

Unconscious Bias Training. Programme Overview. 1 Day or ½ Day? +44 (0) /

Unconscious Bias Training. Programme Overview. 1 Day or ½ Day? +44 (0) / ½ Programme Overview Discrimination is destructive and counter-productive. We know that people discriminate consciously either due to prejudice or through ignorance. What is less known is that people often

More information

Developing a Comprehensive and One-Dimensional Subjective Well-Being Measurement: Evidence from a Belgian Pilot Survey

Developing a Comprehensive and One-Dimensional Subjective Well-Being Measurement: Evidence from a Belgian Pilot Survey Developing a Comprehensive and One-Dimensional Subjective Well-Being Measurement: Evidence from a Belgian Pilot Survey Marc Hooghe 1 1 University of Leuven (Belgium), e-mail: Marc.Hooghe@soc.kuleuven.be

More information

CHAPTER 3 METHOD AND PROCEDURE

CHAPTER 3 METHOD AND PROCEDURE CHAPTER 3 METHOD AND PROCEDURE Previous chapter namely Review of the Literature was concerned with the review of the research studies conducted in the field of teacher education, with special reference

More information

Reading and maths skills at age 10 and earnings in later life: a brief analysis using the British Cohort Study

Reading and maths skills at age 10 and earnings in later life: a brief analysis using the British Cohort Study Reading and maths skills at age 10 and earnings in later life: a brief analysis using the British Cohort Study CAYT Impact Study: REP03 Claire Crawford Jonathan Cribb The Centre for Analysis of Youth Transitions

More information

What do Americans know about inequality? It depends on how you ask them

What do Americans know about inequality? It depends on how you ask them Judgment and Decision Making, Vol. 7, No. 6, November 2012, pp. 741 745 What do Americans know about inequality? It depends on how you ask them Kimmo Eriksson Brent Simpson Abstract A recent survey of

More information

Unit 1 Exploring and Understanding Data

Unit 1 Exploring and Understanding Data Unit 1 Exploring and Understanding Data Area Principle Bar Chart Boxplot Conditional Distribution Dotplot Empirical Rule Five Number Summary Frequency Distribution Frequency Polygon Histogram Interquartile

More information

Charitable Giving as a Gift Exchange: Evidence from a Field Experiment

Charitable Giving as a Gift Exchange: Evidence from a Field Experiment DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 1148 Charitable Giving as a Gift Exchange: Evidence from a Field Experiment Armin Falk May 2004 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor

More information