Economic Perspectives on Alcohol Taxation. and

Similar documents
Economics and Alcohol Taxation

SLIDE 5: Graph of Trends in Federal Alcoholic Beverage Taxes

The Effects of Excise Tax on Beer Consumption

The Economics of Alcohol and Cancer/Chronic Disease

ECONOMIC MODELS OF ADDICTION AND APPLICATIONS TO CIGARETTE SMOKING AND OTHER SUBSTANCE ABUSE

ImpacTeen is part of Bridging the Gap: Research Informing Practice for Healthy Youth Behavior, supported by the Robert Wood Johnson Foundation and

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE IMPACT OF PRICE, AVAILABILITY, AND ALCOHOL CONTROL POLICIES ON BINGE DRINKING IN COLLEGE

The Fiscal Impact of Raising Texas Alcohol Taxes

The Effects of Alcohol Excise Tax Increases on. Public Health in Maryland

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ALCOHOL CONSUMPTION AND TAX DIFFERENTIALS BETWEEN BEER, WINE AND SPIRITS. Working Paper No. 3200

MPA BURNING ISSUES CONFERENCE. Thursday, November 10, 2016

THE EFFECTS OF ALCOHOL EXCISE TAX INCREASES ON PUBLIC HEALTH AND SAFETY IN TEXAS

GERMANY. Recorded adult (15+) alcohol consumption by type of alcoholic beverage (in % of pure alcohol), Spirits 20%

MARIJUANA AND YOUTH Rosalie Liccardo Pacula, Ph.D. Michael Grossman, Ph.D. Frank J. Chaloupka, Ph.D. Patrick M. O Malley, Ph.D.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ALCOHOL REGULATION AND CRIME. Christopher Carpenter Carlos Dobkin. Working Paper

Smoking, Drinking, and Binge Drinking: An Empirical Study of the Role of Price on Consumption by High School Seniors

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INDIVIDUAL BEHAVIORS AND SUBSTANCE USE: THE ROLE OF PRICE. Michael Grossman

ROMANIA. Upper-middle Income Data source: United Nations, data range

Health Benefits of Increases in Alcohol and Cigarette Taxes

SLOVENIA. Recorded adult (15+) alcohol consumption by type of alcoholic beverage (in % of pure alcohol), Spirits 13%

KAZAKHSTAN. Upper-middle Income Data source: United Nations, data range

A Review of Alcohol Pricing and its Effects on Alcohol Consumption and Alcohol-Related Harm

ARMENIA. Lower-middle Income Data source: United Nations, data range

I. INTRODUCTION. consumption and violence (see Miczek et al., 1993, for a complete review of the literature).

LITHUANIA. Upper-middle Income Data source: United Nations, data range

UNITED KINGDOM OF GREAT BRITAIN AND NORTHERN IRELAND (the)

NORWAY. Recorded adult (15+) alcohol consumption by type of alcoholic beverage (in % of pure alcohol), Other 2% Wine 31%

Volume Title: Controlling Crime: Strategies and Tradeoffs. Volume Author/Editor: Philip J. Cook, Jens Ludwig, and Justin McCrary

FACT SHEET Alcohol and Price. Background. 55 million European adults drink to dangerous levels.

Table 1. Summary of the types of alcohol taxes applied by category of alcohol product. 12

DO YOUTHS SUBSTITUTE ALCOHOL AND MARIJUANA? SOME ECONOMETRIC EVIDENCE. Working Paper No. 4662

Global Survey on Alcohol and Health. and. Global Information System on Alcohol and Health

ABSTRACT. The purpose of this study is to examine the question of whether alcohol or drug use causes

Economics of youth drug use, addiction and gateway effects

Attracting Funding for Cancer Prevention Using Economic and Fiscal Tools

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ENOOGENOUS DRINKING AGE LAWS AND HIGHWAY MORTALITY RATES OF YOUNG DRIVERS. Henry Saffer.

Initial Report of Oregon s State Epidemiological Outcomes Workgroup. Prepared by:

Alcohol Anderson County Tennessee United States Year Information Year Information Year Information

Why Changes in Price Matter When Thinking About Marijuana Policy: A Review of the Literature on the Elasticity of Demand

In preparation : The impact of raising minimum alcohol prices in Saskatchewan, Canada: Improving public health while raising government revenue?

Volume URL: Chapter Author: Henry Saffer, Frank J. Chaloupka. Chapter URL:

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CIGARETTES AND ALCOHOL: SUBSTITUTES OR COMPLEMENTS? Sandra L. Decker Amy Ellen Schwartz

FACT SHEET: Alcohol Facts

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES RISK TOLERANCE AND ALCOHOL DEMAND AMONG ADULTS AND OLDER ADULTS. Dhaval Dave Henry Saffer

Policy Summary Distance Limitations Applied to New Alcohol Outlets Near Universities, Colleges, and Primary and Secondary Schools

Higher rate now: Why excise tax on tobacco is long overdue for an increase

NATIONAL COUNCIL ON ALCOHOLISM AND DRUG DEPENDENCE - NEW JERSEY ALCOPOPS: DISGUISED DANGER

Alcohol and marijuana use among college students: economic complements or substitutes?

Alcohol Policy and Social Change: Creating Safer Community Environments

MAGNITUDE OF ALCOHOL-RELATED MORTALITY

Ruhm, C. (1996). Alcohol Policies and Highway Vehicle Fatalities. Journal of Health Economics 15(4):

Minimum alcohol price policies in action: The Canadian Experience

The Negative Consequences of Alcohol Consumption and the Analysis of Variables that Can Affect or Reduce Alcohol Consumption

Cigarette Consumption: Estimating the Effects of an Excise Cigarette Tax in California

ALCOHOL PRICES, CONSUMPTION, AND TRAFFIC FATALITIES

Underage Drinking. Underage Drinking Statistics

TOBACCO TAXATION, TOBACCO CONTROL POLICY, AND TOBACCO USE

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES. AN INVESTIGATION OF THE EFFECTS OF ALCOHOL POLICIES ON YOUTH STDs. Michael Grossman Robert Kaestner Sara Markowitz

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ALCOHOL TAXES AND LABOR MARKET OUTCOMES. Dhaval Dave Robert Kaestner. Working Paper 8562

Women and Substance Abuse in Nevada. A Special Report

Slippery When Wet: The Effects of Local Alcohol Access Laws on Highway Safety. Reagan Baughman Center for Policy Research Syracuse University

BACKGROUND PAPER. Executive Summary. March 2004, Number 43. Patrick Fleenor. Chief Economist Fiscal Economics, Inc.

AUSTRALIAN CHRONIC DISEASE PREVENTION ALLIANCE. Submission to Senate Standing Committee on Community Affairs

Keg Registration, Server Training, Beer Excise Tax and Underage Drinking: A Multi-level Analysis

Are Illegal Drugs Inferior Goods?

THE abuse of alcohol is the leading risk factor for disability and premature death in the world.

Generating Revenue & Cutting Costs The Health & Economic Benefits of Tobacco Control

The Effectiveness of Tobacco Tax & Price Policies for Tobacco Control Frank J. Chaloupka University of Illinois at Chicago

Ending Prohibition? Proposition 19, Marijuana Legalization, and the Implications for Mexico October 14, 2010 Event Summary

Alcohol Policy and Social Change: Creating Safer Community Environments James F. Mosher, JD Alcohol Policy Consultations

Minimum Unit Pricing & Banning Below Cost Selling: Estimated policy impacts in England 2014/15

Alcohol taxation: impacts of policy inconsistencies

Reducing Alcohol-impaired Driving: Maintaining Current Minimum Legal Drinking Age (MLDA) Laws

LATVIA. Recorded adult per capita consumption (age 15+) Lifetime abstainers

The Economic Costs of Alcohol Abuse in Alaska, 2016 Update

STATE ALCOHOL EXCISE TAXES MAY HAVE LITTLE EFFECT ON DRUNK DRIVING FATALITIES Robert McClelland and John Iselin November 27, 2017

Alcohol as a public health issue in croatia. Croatian Institute of Public Health Prof. Danijela Štimac Grbić, MD.,PhD.,MPH.

RAISING CIGARETTE TAXES REDUCES SMOKING, ESPECIALLY AMONG KIDS (AND THE CIGARETTE COMPANIES KNOW IT)

ImpacTeen is part of Bridging the Gap: Research Informing Practice for Healthy Youth Behavior, supported by the Robert Wood Johnson Foundation and

Tobacco use is Wisconsin s

Alcohol Indicators Report Executive Summary

How Alcohol Outlets Affect Neighborhood Violence

State Alcohol Excise Taxes May Have Little Effect on Drunk Driving Fatalities.

Alcohol Consumption in Australia: An Application of the Ordered Generalised Extreme Value Model

With drug addiction, a distinction must be made between physical and psychological dependence

THE EFFECT OF ALCOHOL PROHIBITION ON ILLICIT-DRUG-RELATED CRIMES* STACY DICKERT-CONLIN, Syracuse University. and. JOHN PEPPER University of Virginia

How Price Increases Reduce Tobacco Use

BD295 Professor Wesley Perkins Spring 2018 Prevalence and Consequences of Alcohol Use and Abuse

Module 6: Substance Use

Rational addiction to alcohol: panel data analysis of liquor consumption

Substance Abuse in Washington, D.C.

Literature Review: Assessing Wisconsin s Alcohol Abuse and How to Influence Change

CANAM INTERVENTIONS. Addiction

Magnitude. SELECT A TOPIC...

BD 295: Alcohol Use and Abuse Introductory Lectures Professor Wesley Perkins Spring 2016 Socio-Cultural Patterns of Use and Consequences of Abuse

Measure of frequency to be reported

Q8. Is reducing the availability of alcohol effective in reducing deaths from suicide, suicide attempts and acts of self-harm?

The Meaning of the November Ballot Initiative to Legalize Recreational Marijuana

A Simple Demand Supply Model of Alcohol Consumption in India Kanupriya Suthar Independent Researcher, India

Transcription:

Economic Perspectives on Alcohol Taxation Frank J. Chaloupka University of Illinois at Chicago and National Bureau of Economic Research and Michael Grossman, CUNY and NBER Henry Saffer, Kean College and NBER Adit Laixuthai, Chulalongkorn University Henry Wechsler, Harvard University Rosalie Liccardo Pacula, RAND and NBER Ismail Sirtalan, New York Hospital Association Sara Markowitz, CUNY and NBER

Rationales for Alcohol Taxation Revenue Generation Public Health Improvement Economic Efficiency

Revenue Generation 1791 First federal excise tax: 9 cents per gallon 1794 Whiskey Rebellion response to near tripling of tax Raised several times during both World Wars, Korean War 1951 federal taxes for: Beer: $9 per barrel Distilled spirits: $10.50 per proof gallon Wine (unfortified): 17 cents per gallon

Revenue Generation (continued) More recent increases for deficit reduction Current federal taxes for: Beer: $18 per barrel Distilled spirits: $13.50 per proof gallon Wine (unfortified): $1.07 per gallon

Federal Alcohol Taxes Per Ounce of Ethanol June 1997 Dollars $1.20 $1.00 $0.80 Distilled Spirits Tax Beer Tax Wine Tax Dollars $0.60 $0.40 $0.20 $0.00 1951 1956 1961 1966 1971 1976 Year 1981 1986 1991 1996

Price Elasticity of Demand Revenue generating potential of alcohol taxes depends on price sensitivity of demand for alcoholic beverages Price Elasticity of Demand defined as the percentage change in consumption resulting from a one percent increase in price

Price Elasticity of Demand for Alcohol Estimated price elasticities (Leung and Phelps, 1993): Beer: -0.3 Wine: -1.0 Distilled Spirits: -1.5 Larger long-run effects of price on addictive consumption (Grossman, Chaloupka and Sirtalan, 1998)

Taxing Alcohol to Improve Public Health Based on argument that higher alcoholic beverage taxes reduce morbidity, mortality, and other consequences of alcohol use and abuse Large/growing literature from economics examining effects on accidents, violence/other crime, health consequences, illicit drug use, and more

Public Health: Accidents Large economics literature on impact of alcohol prices and taxes on drinking and driving and alcohol-related motor vehicle accidents 10 percent increase in price would reduce probability of drinking and driving by 7.4 percent (males) and 8.1 percent (females). Larger impact on underage drinkers (Kenkel, 1993).

Public Health: Accidents (continued) Policy indexing federal beer tax to inflation since 1951 would reduce total annual motor vehicle accident fatalities by 11.5 percent (32.1 percent for 18-20 year olds) (Chaloupka, Saffer and Grossman, 1993) Youth non-fatal motor vehicle accidents inversely related to beer taxes (Chaloupka and Laixuthai, 1997)

Public Health: Accidents Less extensive literature suggests higher alcoholic beverage taxes would reduce injuries and deaths in other accidents: Example: 25 percent increase in 1992 federal beer tax would have reduced work-loss days from non-fatal workplace accidents by 4.6 million and lost productivity by $491 million (Oshfeldt and Morrisey, 1997).

Public Health: Violence Large literature linking alcohol abuse to violence Early estimates suggest higher taxes would reduce violent crime (Cook and Moore, 1993) Doubling federal beer tax would reduce homicides by 3 percent, rapes by 2 percent, robberies by 4.7 percent, and total crime by 1.3 percent (Chaloupka and Saffer, 1992)

Public Health: Violence (continued) 10 percent rise in federal beer tax would reduce probability of child abuse by 2.2 percent and all violence towards children by 1.1 percent, or 1.1 million (Markowitz and Grossman, 1997) 10 percent rise in price of pure alcohol would reduce the probability of wife abuse by 10 percent or more (Markowitz, 1999)

Public Health: Violence (continued) Higher beer prices would reduce violence and other problem behaviors on college campuses (Markowitz and Grossman, 1998)

Public Health: Liver Cirrhosis and Other Alcohol-Related Disease $1 increase in distilled spirits tax would lower cirrhosis deaths by 5.4 to 10.8 percent (Cook and Tauchen, 1982) Long-run price elasticity of cirrhosis deaths -1.3 (Chaloupka, Grossman, Becker and Murphy, 1992) Higher taxes reduce other alcohol related deaths (Sloan, Reilly and Schenzler, 1994)

Public Health: Polysubstance Use Higher beer taxes reduce the likelihood of marijuana use among young adults (Pacula, 1998) and adults (Chaloupka and Saffer, 1997). They also reduce the current likelihood of cocaine and heroin use (Chaloupka and Saffer, 1997). Recent evidence suggests that higher beer taxes may reduce future marijuana use as well (Pacula, 1998).

Economic Efficiency and Alcohol Taxation Alcoholic beverage taxes can correct for the external costs associated with alcohol consumption (in absence of taxes, prices understate the social costs of alcohol use) Complicated in the case of alcohol since not all drinking results in external costs (external benefits of moderate drinking?)

Economic Efficiency and Alcohol Taxation Optimal (economically efficient) tax depends on: magnitude of social costs of alcohol use and abuse relative numbers of abusive and non-abusive drinkers relative price responsiveness of abusive and non-abusive drinkers (Pogue and Sgontz, 1989)

Economic Efficiency (continued) Pogue and Sgontz (1989) estimate that 1983 alcohol taxes were about half the efficient level of these taxes based on their model/ best guess using a wide range of estimates. Manning, et al. (1989) estimate on optimal tax of 48 cents per ounce in 1985 (compared to average tax of 23 cents per oz.) Kenkel (1996) estimates optimal tax of about 106 percent of net of tax price

Economic Efficiency (continued) Saffer and Chaloupka (1994) extend the Pogue and Sgontz approach to examine the relative taxation of distilled spirits, wine, and beer. Estimate weighted average optimal tax 2.3 times the 1991 level Estimates support tax system closer to equalization across all alcoholic beverages

Summary Increases in alcoholic beverage taxes and prices lead to significant reductions in drinking Increases in alcohol taxes will generate significant new tax revenues Long-run effects of price on alcohol demand larger than short-run effects Youth and young adults more responsive to price changes than adults

Summary (continued) Increases in alcoholic beverage taxes and prices reduce many consequences of alcohol use and abuse, including accidents, violence and other crime, alcohol-related morbidity and mortality, illicit drug use, and more Estimates of optimal alcoholic beverage taxes well above the current levels of these taxes

Policy Options Economic and Public Health arguments support: significant increases in alcoholic beverage tax rates indexing of alcohol taxes to the rate of inflation equalization of taxes on alcohol contained in different alcoholic beverages tax increases as part of a comprehensive program aimed at reducing alcohol use and abuse