RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 1. European Journal of Personality, 2001, 15, S19-S35

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 1. European Journal of Personality, 2001, 15, S19-S35"

Transcription

1 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 1 European Journal of Personality, 2001, 15, S19-S35 Individual differences and social norms: The distinction between reciprocators and prosocials Marco Perugini University of Essex, United Kingdom Marcello Gallucci Free University of Amsterdam, The Netherlands Running Heading: RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS Address correspondence to: Dr Marco Perugini, Department of Psychology, University of Essex Wivenhoe Park, Colchester CO4 3SQ, United Kingdom mperug@essex.ac.uk; Tel ; Fax

2 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 2 ABSTRACT Reciprocity is in this contribution compared with cooperation, hostility and prosociality, in order to distinguish its peculiar theoretical and empirical characteristics. Two studies are presented. Study 1 (n=166) is based on the distinction between the mechanism of reciprocity and the consequent behavior that this mechanism produces. It is shown that participants have a clear implicit theory of the personality traits underlying reciprocal behavior, and these traits are well-differentiated with respect to traits underlying cooperation and hostility. Study 2 (n=134) is based on the distinction between reciprocity as a goal and reciprocity as a strategy to achieve equality. Results show that individuals with high internalization of the norm of reciprocity allocate payoffs as a function of the valence of other's past behavior, whereas this feature is irrelevant for individuals with high prosocial orientation.

3 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 3 A peculiar feature of reciprocity is that in order to reciprocate, individuals might behave in completely different ways. Reciprocity can be displayed in a plethora of behaviors, as returning a favor, taking revenge of someone, exchanging proportionate goods, punishing a previously received wrong, kissing back a child, and so forth. The fact that reciprocal behavior manifests itself through actions of different nature, however, has often led scholars to equate the mechanism with the object of the mechanism. Reciprocal behavior has been interpreted as a form of cooperation, altruism, hostility, among many others actions and orientations. A second important feature of reciprocity is that when individuals want to reciprocate, they might actually intend to achieve something else. Reciprocity is in fact a powerful mechanism to shape others' actions by delivering rewards and punishments. This makes reciprocating individuals able to achieve a remarkable number of interdependent outcomes, otherwise out of the individual's reach. Equity, cooperation, equality, and even material selfinterest can be maximized by means of patterns of reciprocal behavior. This characteristic, however, has often led to the conclusion that reciprocity is a mere strategy, that is, a means to obtain a variety of goals. Due to the aforementioned sources of confusion, and therefore to a consequently unspecific definition of the concept and mechanism of reciprocity, the large literature on reciprocity has not been very productive in the study of the personality traits and individual differences that specifically refer to reciprocal behavior in interdependence situations. Attention has been paid more to related concepts, above all cooperation and individual difference in prosociality. This contribution seeks to investigate the unique characteristics of reciprocity in the domain of individual differences, by differentiating reciprocity from prosociality both in terms of behavior and in the corresponding personality traits. By endorsing a trait-situational perspective (Ten Berge & De Raad, in press), we investigate the concept of reciprocity

4 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 4 among lay people, showing that reciprocity is clearly differentiated from cooperation. Furthermore, by taking an experimental perspective, we show that individual differences in reciprocity lead to unique predictions of behavior, clearly distinguishable from individual differences in prosociality and preferences for cooperation. The theoretical arguments upon which this differentiation is based can be outlined by addressing three basic questions: what is reciprocity, why people reciprocate and who reciprocates. What is reciprocity? Reciprocity is not cooperation nor it is just a consequence of having a positive attitude towards cooperation. Sometimes in the literature there has been confusion between these two concepts, especially because the concept of reciprocal altruism has been often equated with reciprocity, therefore emphasizing the positive side of reciprocity (Trivers, 1971). Reciprocity is not hostility too, even though the mechanism of reciprocity encompasses also various forms of hostile and negative behaviors. Reciprocity is a mechanism that can lead to positive and negative forms of behavior depending on the specific context eliciting a reciprocal action. This conditional nature of reciprocity was expressed by Gouldner first (1960) and elaborated upon with the concept of Tit-for-Tat (Axelrod, 1984; & Dion, 1988). The emphasis has been generally placed on the strategic value of reciprocity as a norm able to increase future payoffs and deter defection, given some structural features of the interaction. One of these structural features that has been traditionally emphasized is the presence of repeated interactions between the individuals (Axelrod, 1984; Kreps, Milgrom, Roberts, & Wilson, 1982). However, as we shall argue in the following pages, recent experimental results have clarified that the presence of repeated interactions is not a necessary condition to observe reciprocal behavior among some participants (Gallucci & Perugini, 2000; Van Lange, 1999). Reciprocity, therefore, is not always a strategy to maximize self-interest.

5 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 5 We maintain that reciprocity is a conditional behavior aimed at reacting to a behavior with another behavior of the same valence (Perugini & Gallucci, 1998; Gallucci & Perugini, 2000 ). Reciprocity is clearly differentiated from cooperation and hostility because it is conditional and it matches actions according to their valence: A positive actions is reciprocated with positive actions, a negative action with negative ones. What remains unclear from this analysis is whether these differences have actual correspondence in real life. Do people differentiate between reciprocators, cooperators, and hostile persons? And if so, what kind of criteria are they using? Is there any implicit conception of these three personality dimensions used by lay people? Why people reciprocate? Obviously, a specific instance of reciprocal behavior can be performed for a variety of reasons and by a variety of persons and it can be explained from different perspectives. Reciprocity has been observed in living beings with undoubtedly different motivations and personalities, such as vampire bats (DeNault, & McFarlane, 1995), hyenas, (Trivers, 1971), apes (de Wall, 1992), humans of different ages and cultures (Goldstein, Field, & Healy, 1989; Patterson & Bettini, 1993; Windle, 1994), a result that by itself prompts for different possible answers to our present question. Striving for self-interest has been very often suggested as a motivational basis of reciprocal behavior (Axelrod, 1984; & Dion, 1988). When the interdependent situation is repeated over time, reciprocal behavior is not exploitable by more selfish strategies and it can profit from mutual cooperation. This strategic value has been supported by formal analyses (Kreps, Milgrom, Roberts, & Wilson, 1982), computer simulations (Axelrod, 1984), and experimental results (Hoffman, McCabe & Smith, 1998; Komorita & Parks, 1999). A second explanation has been provided within the tradition of interdependence theory (Kelley & Thibaut, 1978). In this framework, individuals are expected to have different preferences concerning other's outcomes in situation of interdependence of outcomes.

6 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 6 Interdependence theory assumes that the given matrix representing the mutual outcomes of the interaction depending on the combinations of behaviors is actually transformed by people in the effective matrix, whereby individuals transform the given outcomes according to their social orientations. Social orientations have the quality of a personality dimensions, in that it is assumed that people have stable and reliable preferences that guide their behavior in situations of interdependence. Among the several possible transformations, attention has been devoted to three of these personality types : prosocial, who are tending to maximize outcomes for both themselves and others and minimize the differences, individualists, tending to maximize their own outcomes regardless of others outcomes, and competitors, tending to maximize the relative advantage of their outcomes over others outcomes. Research has shown that prosocials approach situations of interdependence in a cooperative manner and continue to do so until the other fails to cooperate (McClintock & Liebrand, 1988; Sattler & Kerr, 1991). Recently, Van Lange (1999) has proposed an integrative model of social value orientations where the traditional emphasis on the maximization of joint outcomes in defining prosocials has been integrated with the assumption that they are also motivated to achieve equality in outcomes. This latter conceptualization can be used to explain and predict some forms of reciprocal behavior also in not-repeated interactions. In other words, prosocials are assumed to strive also to restore equality of outcomes and this can lead in turn to reciprocate their partner's behavior such that this equality is achieved (see also De Cremer and Van Lange, 2001). We have adopted a wider perspective (Perugini & Gallucci, 1998). By taking a pluralistic view on motivation, we have argued that reciprocity can be defined both as a strategy and as a goal itself. This view is based on the analysis of reciprocal behavior in terms of means and ends. Reciprocity can be instrumental to achieve a specific goal, and actors aware of its effects can employ it accordingly. Thus, a rational actor that is able to foresee the long term effect of reciprocity on her outcomes, can act in a reciprocal way because she

7 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 7 believes that this is the best way to gain as much as possible (Axelrod, 1984). Likewise, a prosocial actor who wants to achieve equitable allocations of resources can employ a reciprocal behavior in order to balance the amount of resources that are exchanged in the situation (Van Lange, 1999). However, it is possible to identify a type of reciprocity whereby behavior and its underlying motivation are convergent and reciprocity can be defined as a goal: reciprocity as an internalized norm. A key feature of this definition is that internalized reciprocity should be viewed as an individual preference, since it represents a personal tendency to behave in a reciprocal way, regardless of strategic considerations. Therefore, the underlying motivation sustaining a reciprocating behavior can be endogenous rather than functional to achieve some alternative goal. Reciprocity can be the goal per se. This distinction echoes a general distinction between social and personal norms (Cialdini, Kallgren, & Reno, 1991; Etzioni, 1989; Kerr, Garst, Lewandowski, & Harris, 1997; Schwartz, 1977), whereby the latter can be conceived as social norms that become internalized via social learning and acquire a motivational drive on their own. Indeed, individuals holding internalized social norms (or personal norms) are likely to conform to their dictates even when they are not observed or sanctioned externally, through the anticipation of self-punishments and rewards based on their own internalized values (Schwartz, 1977). The distinction between reciprocity as a mean and reciprocity as a goal has two crucial consequences: First, it is possible to clarify what situational and interpersonal features are necessary for certain behaviors to be acted. Second, it is possible to clarify what traits are necessary for a particular form of reciprocal behavior to be acted. The first consequence is well exemplified by considering reciprocal behavior when instrumental for self-interest. This behavior should be acted only when future profits are available, they can be obtained via reciprocal behavior and actors are able to foresee this possibility. As we mentioned earlier, experimental results have shown that reciprocity is

8 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 8 observable when none of these conditions are satisfied. Using situations where no repetition was possible, and the reciprocal strategies were always outperformed by unconditional selfishness, it has been shown that a fair proportion of the experimental sample employed reciprocity as the behavioral rule to allocate resources in various interdependent situations (Bolton, & Zwick, 1995; Gallucci & Perugini, 2000; Gallucci & Perugini, 2001). These results clearly suggest that whereas material self-interest can explain some instances of reciprocal behaviors, it cannot be the sole underlying motivation of reciprocity. It is equally possible to specify the situational features that are necessary for prosociality to explain reciprocal behaviors. Prosociality leads individuals to reciprocate because prosocials prefer equitable outcomes over advantageous outcomes (Van Lange, 1999). Thus, prosocials should be concerned only with the outcomes of their behavior and should react only to the other's allocation outcome. On the other hand, the norm of reciprocity concerns the reaction to the valence of others' behavior, with the outcome per se being only one component of the overall valence. Thus, prosociality should lead to reciprocal equality, whereas the internalized norm of reciprocity should lead to reciprocal behavior even when equality in the outcomes is not the consequence of the action. This latter analysis enables us to outline a further distinction, which brings us to the core of this contribution: the distinction between the effects of individual differences in the internalized norm of reciprocity and prosociality. Who reciprocates? The definition of reciprocity as an internalized norm has been encapsulated in a formal model developed using game theory (Perugini & Gallucci, 1998; Gallucci & Perugini, 2000). A basic assumption of this model of reciprocity is that there are individual differences in abiding by the prescription of the norm. In their experiment, as well as in other experiments (Gallucci & Perugini, 2001; Perugini & Gallucci, 2001), it has been found that some individuals systematically do reciprocate whereas others do not. The question therefore

9 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 9 becomes who are those individuals who reciprocate even when there are no material or social advantages in so doing. According to Van Lange (1999), prosocials, as defined by means of the Social Value Orientation triple-dominance measure (Kuhlman & Marshello, 1975), show evidence of reciprocal behavior (also called behavioral assimilation) even in single-trial prisoner s dilemma. Prosocials level of cooperation was found to be systematically influenced by the partner's cooperation, with more cooperation following a partner's choice of cooperation. Therefore, in this line of thinking, reciprocal behaviors can be considered as a result of being a prosocial, which in turn implies, as re-defined by Van Lange (1999), being motivated to both maximizing joint outcomes and achieving equality in outcomes. This latter goal can be achieved both through punishments and rewards and, depending on the specific situation, can therefore lead to predict reciprocal behavior. According to our analysis, reciprocity can be a goal on itself, and thus reciprocal behavior is not limited to the purpose of equality. If one considers reciprocity as a personal norm, then it is conceivable that individuals will differ directly in how much they are willing to follow the norm. In other words, it can be argued that there are reliable individual differences in the motivation to reciprocate per se rather than on some other personality dimensions (e.g., prosociality) that in turn would lead to reciprocate. Indeed, Perugini and Gallucci have recently developed such an individual difference measure, called Personal Norm of Reciprocity (PNR) scale, and validated it successfully in a series of studies (Gallucci & Perugini, 2001; Perugini & Gallucci, 2001; Perugini, Gallucci, Presaghi, & Ercolani, 2001). The PNR measures three dimensions: positive reciprocity, focusing on positive reactions to positively valued behaviors, negative reciprocity, focusing on negative reactions to negatively valued behaviors, and beliefs in reciprocity, concerning the personal belief that both forms of reciprocity are widely adopted by many people and generally effective in interpersonal and social interactions (Perugini et al., 2001). We argue that these

10 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 10 constructs of reciprocity should have a main role in predicting individual differences in reciprocal behavior, especially when it is a consequence of a personal motivation rather than of material convenience. Reciprocators are not (necessarily) prosocials Even though there is some empirical evidence showing that prosocials may reciprocate even when there is no obvious strategic convenience (Van Lange, 1999; De Cremer & Van Lange, 2001), we argue that in the general case reciprocators are not prosocials. The underlying mechanism of reciprocity is to react to someone else action with an action of the same valence, such as positive behaviors are rewarded and negative behaviors punished. The main motivation of reciprocators therefore is to sanction someone else behavior, including also behaviors which are expected rather than already acted. Their concern therefore is not so much to restore equality in outcomes, but to match the valence of others' behavior with equivalent behavior. Therefore, the general case is that the mechanisms of reciprocity and of prosociality are different and lead to different behaviors, even though there can be situations whereby, due to the nature of the payoffs and the structure of the interaction, the empirical predictions can be equivalent. Of course, the first key difference is linked to the performance of negative behaviors. Whereas reciprocators, as defined by high scores in the scale of negative reciprocity, can easily resort to forms of negative behaviors (e.g., punishment) if the situation requires (e.g., the other behaved negatively), prosocials are expected to be less prone to act in negative terms (although they might do so, cf. Van Lange, 1999). In other words, prosociality mainly pertains to positive forms of behaviors (e.g., cooperation), whereas reciprocity includes both positive and negative behaviors. A second feature differentiating prosocials from reciprocators is the importance of the valence of someone else behaviors. As a consequence of their reactivity to others actions, reciprocators are expected to be very sensitive to the valence of the action and to take into account factors such as its intentionality. On the other hand, there is nothing in the definition of the prosocials

11 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 11 concerning these issues. The present contribution This contribution presents two studies. The first study endorses a trait-situational perspective (Ten Berge & De Raad, 1999, in press) to investigate the concept of reciprocity among lay people. The focus is on individuating those trait-situation features that can distinguish between reciprocity, cooperation and hostility. The second study develops further some of the findings of the first study, and focuses on the differential effects of the norm of reciprocity and prosociality on behavior towards others. Study 1 Different traits can lead to the same behavior. Without a careful study of the situational contingencies within which behaviors are performed the risk is to fail to appreciate this ifthen connection (Wright & Mischel, 1987). Moreover, not all personality characteristics are expressed in all situations. As argued by Ten Berge and De Raad (1999), certain traits can be expressed preferentially in certain situations. Reciprocity is one of such traits. Suppose that Mary observes John acting very kindly towards Jim: she would be tempted to conclude that John is cooperative. However, if soon afterwards Carolyn sees John acting unkindly towards David she might arrive at the opposite conclusion: John is a hostile person. One way to solve this apparent inconsistency is to look for the situational contingencies characterizing John s behavior. If Mary and Carolyn would have seen that, say, Jim was behaving very nicely with John whereas David was behaving very rudely, then they might have come to the conclusion that John is a reciprocator. In fact, reciprocity is leading to both kind and unkind behaviors depending on the previous history of the interaction. The valence of the behavior performed by the other in the interaction is the key factor that is assumed to shape the reciprocal reaction. On the other hand, cooperation and hostility represent forms of relatively unconditional behavior. Cooperators and hostile persons are assumed to behave nicely and rudely, respectively, in a generalized way and without a strong modulation of their behavior

12 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 12 as a function of the previous history of the interaction and should therefore be less sensitive to the valence of someone else previous behavior. Obviously, it is likely that there will be limits to this inclination to behave kindly or unkindly, but these limits will be typically biased in the direction of the personality disposition (e.g., cooperators will tend to cooperate even in conditions where average people will not do so). In this study we investigate whether lay people actually differentiate between reciprocity, cooperation and hostility and, if so, whether they use the same principle of behavior conditionality that we have sketched so far. Method Participants and procedure. One-hundred-sixty-six participants were recruited at the University of Rome. Approximately one third of the sample was composed of friends, parents or relatives of undergraduate students, who composed the remaining two thirds of the total sample. Fiftyseven were males and 109 females, with an average age of 28.3 years (SD=12.2). They were given a booklet, containing also some unrelated questionnaires, where they were asked to write at least 1 situation for each of the trait reciprocity, cooperativeness, and hostility. The instructions were a slight modification of those used by Ten Berge and De Raad (in press). In particular, after a brief presentation of the aim of the study, participants were encouraged to indicate situations and behaviors that would demonstrate that somebody has a given personality trait. They were asked to use the form When [event] [behavior]. Some examples concerning an unrelated personality trait (recklessness) were provided (e.g, When s/he drinks, s/he does not bother if after s/he has to drive the car ) in order to familiarize the participant with the task. Participants were encouraged to write at least one and in any case no more than 10 of these sentences for each of 3 traits, limiting their time to no more than 5 minutes for each trait. The instructions were followed by three pages containing space for up to 10 sentences for each trait. The personality dimensions were simply introduced as

13 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 13 reciprocator- somebody who reciprocates, cooperator somebody who cooperates, and hostile somebody who is hostile, in order to rely on participants implicit theory rather than providing a more exhaustive but possibly biasing specific definition of each trait. Coding of the sentences and hypotheses. The sentences were coded by two independent raters according to three criteria. First, the part concerning the stem [event] was coded in terms of valence, negative vs neutral vs positive. The same coding in terms of valence was done on the stem [behavior]. Finally, the unit [event] [behavior] was coded in terms of action congruence, different vs same, that is whether the behavior was congruent with the event. The frequencies of these three criteria for the three dimensions of reciprocity, cooperativeness and hostility represented the dependent variables. The first set of hypotheses concerns the valence of the action. We expect that the valence of the event and the behavior would tend to be similar for reciprocity. The mechanism of reciprocity prescribes to return good for good and bad for bad (Gouldner, 1960). Therefore, we expect that this conditional link would be reflected in a very high frequency of sentences whereby a positive event is followed by a positive behavior and a negative event by a negative behavior. On the contrary, we do not expect such symmetry for cooperativeness and hostility, given that these two traits are reflecting relatively unconditional dispositional inclinations. Moreover, we would expect prevalence of positive [behavior] for cooperativeness and of negative [behavior] for hostility, regardless of the stem [event]. In particular, we also expect that many neutral [event] will be followed by positive [behavior] for cooperativeness and by negative [behavior] by hostility. In other words, we expect that the personality dispositions of cooperativeness and hostility will be reflected in a relatively unconditional preference for positive or negative behavior. The second hypothesis states that there will be action congruency for reciprocity but not for cooperativeness and hostility. The reason is that reciprocity involves giving back what has been received and therefore the congruence between type of event and type of behavior is

14 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 14 more important. Even though it is possible to reciprocate in different kinds, typically the easiest way is to return the same or a very similar action to what it has been previously received, given that this would guarantee equivalence of valence between the other s behavior and the agent s reaction (Batson, 1993). On the contrary, for both cooperativeness and hostility this is not a concern, as both dispositions are relatively unconditional and therefore should not be much affected by this action congruency principle. Results and discussion Participants produced 679 sentences, with an average of 4.09 each. Of these, 79 were not valid, most typically because participants failed to write the sentences as an if-then unit, leaving a total of 600 valid sentences. The agreement between the two coders was high 1, with Cohen s kappa of.80,.93, and.74 for [event], [behavior], [event]-[behavior] congruence, respectively. Disagreements were solved through discussion. The sentences were so distributed: 175 for reciprocity, 185 for cooperativeness, and 240 for hostility. The first hypothesis can be simply checked by ascertaining the correlation between the [event] [behavior] valences separately for each disposition. The Spearman s rho correlation coefficient in the case of reciprocity was highly significant and equal to.81, therefore indicating a strong positive relation between the two valences. For both cooperativeness and hostility the value was low and not significant (.02 and -.00, respectively), meaning that for these two dispositions there was no conditional link between [event] and [behavior]. The cross-tabulations of the [event] [behavior] valences can give more fine-grained information and are relevant to the second part of the first hypothesis (Table1). These can be transformed in conditional probabilities, which are expressing the probability of a specific [behavior] having a certain valence given the valence of an [event] (Table 2). [Insert Tables 1 and 2 about here] The hypotheses are confirmed by the conditional probabilities. For cooperativeness there is a strong bias for positive behaviors, regardless of the valence of the event. In fact, the

15 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 15 probabilities of a positive behavior occurring after a negative, neutral, or positive event are all higher than.90 and very similar to each other, meaning that whichever the event, the behavior is very likely to be positive. An opposite pattern can be found for hostility, with high probability of occurrence of a negative behavior regardless of the valence of the event. Indeed, also in this case the relevant conditional probabilities are very high and approaching unity. The results are more articulated for reciprocity. When an event is negative, the conditional probability of a negative behavior is very high (.954), whereas when it is positive, the probability of a positive behavior occurring afterwards is also very high (.972). However, when the event is neutral, apparently there is a slight bias towards a positive behavior (.667) rather than a neutral one (.333). It has to be noted however that the raw cross-frequencies are very low (6 and 3, respectively) and therefore it remains to be seen whether this result would generalize to a bigger sample of sentences. In general, the results lend full support to our first set of hypotheses. The second hypothesis involves comparing the distribution of action congruency between reciprocity and the null hypothesis of equal distribution, and between the three dispositions (Table 3). [Insert Table 3 about here] The units [event] [behavior] generated for reciprocity tend to be more composed of the same actions than of different actions (75.4% vs 24.6). The proportion is significantly different from an equal distribution (Z=6.72, p<.001). On the contrary, for both cooperativeness and hostility the actions tend to be more different than the same (75.1% and 74.2% of different actions for cooperativeness and reciprocity, respectively). The proportion of same actions is significantly different when comparing reciprocity with cooperativeness (Z=9.58, p<.001) and hostility (Z=10.00, p<.001)., whereas the latter two dispositions do not differ from each other (Z=0.21, p>.05). The results of the first study have shown that reciprocity as a personality disposition

16 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 16 has some specific features. Unlike cooperativeness and hostility, reciprocity has a conditional connotation that emphasizes the matching between what has happened to an agent and what the agent is going to do as a consequence. This symmetry is equally reflected in positive action following positive behaviors and negative actions following negative behaviors. Both cooperativeness and hostility instead present a behavioral bias in the direction congruent with the personality disposition. For cooperators, positive actions are performed regardless whether these were preceded by negative, positive or neutral behaviors, whereas for hostile persons the reverse is true. Moreover, only reciprocators appear to be concerned with reacting in the same way as the action and follow therefore an action congruency principle. This investigation in the lay people conceptions of these three personality dispositions supports therefore the theoretical frame that we have sketched in this contribution. One could argue that results may have been different if we had used the concept of prosociality instead than cooperation 2. It is possible that the former concept would have been less suggestive of a bias towards positive actions. However, it is also the case that whereas the concept of cooperation is often used in everyday language, the concept of prosociality is more technical and less likely to be used by lay people. Nonetheless, we believe that the adoption of a broader spectrum of concepts, such as prosociality, linked to positive and negative interpersonal actions would be an interesting focus for future research. Study 2 The second study investigates further the role of valence for reciprocators. One of the key assumptions of the model of reciprocity is that reciprocators react to the valence of the action and not merely to its material outcome (Gallucci & Perugini, 2000; Perugini & Gallucci, 1998). In other words, reciprocators are expected to be particularly sensitive to factors such as the intention of the interacting agent whereas they should not be particularly influenced by strategic considerations such as the expectation of a repeated interaction or the status of the interacting agent (potential partner vs friend). Some evidence supporting these

17 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 17 claims is already available. Reciprocators, as defined by high scores in the Personal Norm of Reciprocity scale, showed to be particularly sensitive to whether somebody did behave negatively or positively whereas they where not influenced by whether the interaction was expected to be repeated or one shot (Perugini & Gallucci, 2001). There is no rationale instead to hypothesize a similar mechanism for prosocials. It is not clear in fact why factors such as intentionality or valence should affect a prosocial in his/her allocation decisions. The aim of the second study is therefore to test whether reciprocators are particularly sensitive to the valence of someone else behavior, whereas prosocials and individualists are not, and relatively insensitive to the type of relationship. The study involves hypothetical choices without material payoffs. We expect consequently that due to the lack of monetary incentives, participants as a whole will show more generosity than they would should real money be at stake. Therefore, the structure of the situation is such that negative reciprocity will be especially important, given that the increased average payoff allocation would likely not leave any space to detect influences due to positive reciprocity. However, previous results have shown that both dimensions of reciprocity are able to predict deviations from economic rationality (i.e., maximization of personal payoffs) when real payoffs are involved. Indeed, Gallucci & Perugini (2001) found that participants with high scores in both positive and negative reciprocity were willing to ask for strategically irrelevant information, instead than strategically relevant, and reciprocate at a personal cost the other s behavior in a sequential double-dictator game. Likewise, Gallucci & Perugini (2000) found in the so-called Reciprocity Game that positive reciprocators, as defined by high scores in an ad hoc scale that can be considered as a proxy of the positive reciprocity dimension, were willing to sacrifice part of their endowment in order to reward the other agent after a previous positive interaction.

18 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 18 Method Participants and procedure. The total sample was composed of 134 students of the University of Leicester, 23 males and 111 females, with an average age of 21.3 (SD=6.2). Participants were given a selfpaced booklet containing a series of measures. Two personality measures were included in the material. a) Social Value Orientation (SVO). We adopted the triple-dominance measure of social values (Kuhlman & Marshello, 1975) with nine decomposed games (see Van Lange, De Bruin, Otten, & Joireman, 1997 for details and the scoring procedure). On the basis of their choices, participants can be classified as prosocials, individualists, and competitors. If the pattern of choices is inconsistent, respondents are not classified. Participants were classified as 40 prosocials, 67 individualists, 10 competitors and 17 not classifiable. As the number of competitors was too low, we decided to consider in the remaining of the analyses only prosocials and individualists 3. The sample for the analyses was therefore composed of 107 participants, 19 males and 88 females, with an average age of 20.8 (SD=5.7). b) Personal Norm of Reciprocity (PNR) questionnaire. This questionnaire is composed of 27 items measuring three dimensions (9 items each), positive reciprocity, encompassing positive reactions to positively valued behaviors, negative reciprocity, where the emphasis is on matching negative reactions to negatively valued behaviors, and beliefs in reciprocity, concerning the belief that both forms of reciprocity are widely adopted and generally effective. The questionnaire has been validated in two countries, Italy and United Kingdom, in a series of studies reported in Perugini et al. (2001). Besides the two questionnaires, the booklet contained four sets of six allocation matrices in random orders, but fixed for all participants. Each matrix included three possible allocations of payoffs: equitable, advantageous, and disadvantageous for the participants. Each set of matrices was introduced manipulating the other s previous behavior (valence,

19 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 19 positive vs. negative) and the type of relationship (friendship vs expectation of future relationship), according to a 2 x 2 within-subjects factorial design. Participants were asked to choose which allocation they preferred among the three options for each of the six matrices. The dependent variable was the amount of average payoff across the six matrices allocated to the other, therefore ranging from to For instance, the first allocation matrix for the combination positive valence and expectation of future relationship was as follows: The other person is someone whom you do not really know, but you are going to meet very often in the future [expectation of future relationship], and who recently behaved nicely with you [positive valence]. For each of the following six choice situations, circle A, B, or C, depending on which column you prefer most. A B C (1) YOU OTHER For simplicity reasons, the dependent variable has been divided by the maximum possible payoff allocated to the other and multiplied by 100, therefore transforming the value in percentage of allocated payoff relative to the maximum allocation to the other. Hypotheses. The first hypothesis is that the allocation choices will be affected by the valence of the behavior. In particular, we expect that higher allocations will be given to hypothetical persons who behaved nicely previously than to the ones who behaved rudely. This prediction is straightforwardly derived from the norm of reciprocity and it has been already supported in another study (Perugini & Gallucci, 2001). The second hypothesis is that the type of relationship will also influence the allocation, with more payoff allocated to a friend than to somebody with whom one is expected to interact many times in the future, therefore only with the potential of becoming a friend. However, this influence should be particularly relevant when the other behaved rudely, due to consideration of possible future positive returns if the relationship is going to go in a virtuous cycle. Hence, participants might feel inclined to partly forgive the initial negative behavior for the sake of establishing a positive pattern in the future. The third hypothesis therefore states that there will be a significant

20 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 20 interaction between valence and type of relationship. Most interesting for this contribution is the role of personality dimensions, given that we expect an influence of reciprocity on the allocation. However, given the nature of the experimental situation, we expect that negative reciprocity is especially influential and this should result in a significant interaction. In fact, Study 1 has shown that reciprocity, unlike prosociality, is characterized by a conditional if-then action whereby the valence of someone else action is matched. Therefore, the fourth hypothesis is that individual differences in reciprocity will interact with the valence of the behavior and this will be primarily due to negative reciprocity, which should significantly affect allocation choices when the other behaved negatively, regardless of whether s/he was a friend or a potential one. Three ancillary hypotheses are also worth mentioning, even though strictly speaking two of them cannot be defined as such given that they rely on accepting the null hypothesis. Prosociality is expected to have a main effect on allocation choices, with prosocials giving more payoff than individualists. However, it is not expected to have a significant interaction with valence, as the dimension prosocial-individualistic is not expected to be differentially influenced by what the other did in the past. Likewise, but for different reasons, reciprocity is not expected to interact with the type of relationship. In fact, if reciprocity as measured by the PNR scales is primarily an internalized norm, it should not be particularly sensitive to factors such as the type of relationships, which have a more strategic nature. In other words, the reaction of a reciprocator can and should be affected by the valence of someone else action, as this is a crucial element (cf. Gallucci & Perugini, 2000), but it should be relatively unaffected by elements which do not bear strong theoretical relevance, such as the type of relationship. If, contrary to our theoretical analysis, reciprocity is primarily a strategy supported by maximization of material outcomes, then the type of relationship would be affecting the agent s choice, as it could be construed as an indicator of how much is likely that positive future returns will follow the agent s choice (e.g., friends are more likely to give future

21 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 21 positive returns than potential partners). Results and discussion To test the set of hypotheses a mixed ANCOVA 2 (Valence, positive vs negative) x 2 (Future interdependency, present vs absent) x 2 (SVO, prosocial vs. individualist) and using the scores in the three reciprocity scales as covariates was performed. This approach was preferred over the more traditional possibility of dichotomizing the scores in the scales, by creating groups of high and low scorers, as this latter results in reduced statistical power and biased estimates (Maxwell & Delaney, 1993; McClelland & Judd, 1993), which would be even more likely in the present case given the moderate sample size. There was a main effect for Valence (F(1,102)= , p<.001) and for Type of relationship (F(1,102)=66.424, p<.001). More payoff was allocated when the other behaved positively (94.81) than negatively (68.89), and when the interaction was with a friend (86.75) instead than with a potential partner (76.94). The interaction between the two factors was significant (F(1,102)=30.968, p<.001). As depicted in Figure 1, it was mostly due to a much stronger impact of the type of relationship when the behavior was of a negative valence (76.78 with a friend vs with a potential partner, difference of 15.79) than when it was of a positive valence (96.73 with a friend vs with a partner, difference of 3.84). [Insert Figure 1 about here] These results are therefore supporting the first three hypotheses. Concerning the role of the scales of reciprocity, negative reciprocity did have a significant covariate effect (F(1,102)=8.196, p<.01). However, this was qualified by a significant interaction with the Valence (F(1,102)=9.385, p<.001) 4. An inspection of this interaction showed that it was due to a significant decrease in the allocation of the payoffs with increasing scores in negative reciprocity when the valence of the behavior was negative (β=-.37, p<.000) but not when it was positive (β=-.00, p=.962). The fourth hypothesis was therefore fully confirmed. All other ancillary hypotheses were also supported. The SVO type did have a significant main effect

22 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 22 (F(1,102)=18.505, p<.001), meaning that prosocials were allocating more payoff (88.71) than individualists (77.75). However, this main effect was not qualified by any interaction with the other factors, including the valence of the behavior. Finally, none of the scales of reciprocity interacted with the factor type of relationship 5. General discussion The two studies presented in this contribution investigated some of the features of reciprocity as a personality dimension. The first study showed that reciprocators are expected to act conditionally on someone else behavior, unlike cooperators and hostile persons, and tend to return kind for kind via the action congruency principle. The second study showed that reciprocators take particularly into account the valence of someone else behavior, unlike prosocials and individualists, and react by giving less payoffs to the ones who behaved rudely with them, regardless of the type of relationship characterizing their interaction. These two studies, together with other recent studies (Gallucci & Perugini, 2000, 2001; Perugini & Gallucci, 2001; Perugini et al., 2001), are starting to give a more precise characterization of the mechanism of reciprocity and to specify what kind of individual differences modulate this mechanism and how they work. First, the focus is on reciprocity as an internalized mechanism, emphasizing therefore the link between motivation to reciprocate and reciprocal behaviors. Second, a distinction between different but related personality characteristics linked to reciprocity (positive reciprocity, negative reciprocity, beliefs in reciprocity) is introduced. Third, reciprocators are distinguished from hostile persons and from cooperators or prosocials. This last distinction deserves some more comments. Besides the theoretical rationale that we have developed in this contribution and the results of the second study, there is also correlational evidence clearly supporting this distinction (cf. Perugini et al, 2001, Table 3). The SVO and the PNR have been administered to a sample of 146 Italian and 226 English participants. Participants were classified as prosocial or proself (including individualists and competitors, cf. Liebrand & Van Lange, 1991). In Italy, this

23 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 23 reduced SVO was not related to the overall score in the PNR scales, whereas it was related with the PNR scale of positive reciprocity (r=.24, p=.004), meaning that higher scores in the scale were associated with being classified as prosocial. Interestingly, a different pattern emerged in the United Kingdom, with a slight negative correlation with the overall score (r=-.17, p=.011) mainly due to a stronger negative correlation with the PNR scale of negative reciprocity (r=-.28, p<.001). English cooperators tended to have lower scores in the negative reciprocity scale, but not higher scores in the positive reciprocity one (r=.06, p=.34). It appears therefore that there is a modest association between being a prosocial and being a reciprocator and clear evidence of discriminant validity. Furthermore, whether this relation is on the positive or on the negative side of reciprocity depends on the socio-cultural context. These results suggest that prosocials are more likely to reciprocate positive behavior (e.g., to cooperate after the other person cooperated) in Italy, whereas they are less likely to reciprocate negative behavior (e.g., to defect after the other defected) in England, and imply that to cooperate more is not the same as to defect less. Of course, when the choices are dichotomous, to cooperate is equivalent to not defect, but in real life often choices come in degrees and individuals have the opportunity to modulate their behaviors by deciding to cooperate or to defect to a given extent. It is possible that in more realistic conditions the asymmetry between increased cooperation and decreased defection can emerge and can be differentially associated to the different sides of reciprocity, depending on the prevailing norm in a given society concerning the social desirability of reacting negatively or positively to previous behaviors. These speculations should be tested in future research. This contribution has some obvious limitations, especially concerning the second study where no real money was involved. However, the pattern of results is consistent with other studies with monetary incentives (Gallucci & Perugini, 2000, 2001). Moreover, the results of the two studies delineate a consistent pattern characterizing reciprocators and distinguishing them from cooperators or prosocials. We started this contribution claiming that reciprocity is

24 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 24 not cooperation and reciprocators are not prosocials. We can end it with the same claim.

25 RECIPROCATORS AND PROSOCIALS 25 References Axelrod R, Dion D The further evolution of cooperation. Science. 242: Axelrod R The evolution of cooperation. Basic Books: New York. Batson CD Communal and exchange relationships: What is the difference? Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin. 19: Bolton GE, Zwick R Anonymity versus punishment in ultimatum bargaining. Games and Economic Behavior. 10: Cialdini, RB, Kallgren CA, Reno, RR A focus theory of normative conduct: A theoretical refinement and reevaluation of the role of norms in human behavior. In MP Zanna (Ed.), Advances in Experimental Social Psychology (Vol. 24, pp ). New York: Academic Press. Cialdini RB, Trost MR Social influence, social norms, conformity and compliance. In DT Gilbert, ST Fiske, G Lindzey (Eds). The handbook of social psychology, Vol. 2 (4th ed.). (pp ). McGraw Hill: Boston, MA. De Cremer D., Van Lange PAM Why Prosocials Exhibit Greater Cooperation than Proselfs: The Roles of Social Responsibility and Reciprocity. European Journal of Personality, this issue. DeNault LK, McFarlane DA Reciprocal altruism between male vampire bats (Desmodus rotundus). Animal Behaviour. 49: De Waal, F Coalitions as part of reciprocal relations in the Arnhem chimpanzee colony. In Harcourt & F de Waal (Eds), Coalitions and alliances in humans and other animals (pp ). Oxford University Press: Oxford. Etzioni A The moral dimension: Towards a new economics. New York: Free Press. Gallucci M, Perugini M An experimental test of a game-theoretical model of

Emanuela Carbonara. 31 January University of Bologna - Department of Economics

Emanuela Carbonara. 31 January University of Bologna - Department of Economics Game Theory, Behavior and The Law - I A brief introduction to game theory. Rules of the game and equilibrium concepts. Behavioral Games: Ultimatum and Dictator Games. Entitlement and Framing effects. Emanuela

More information

ULTIMATUM GAME. An Empirical Evidence. Presented By: SHAHID RAZZAQUE

ULTIMATUM GAME. An Empirical Evidence. Presented By: SHAHID RAZZAQUE 1 ULTIMATUM GAME An Empirical Evidence Presented By: SHAHID RAZZAQUE 2 Difference Between Self-Interest, Preference & Social Preference Preference refers to the choices people make & particularly to tradeoffs

More information

good reputation, and less chance to be chosen as potential partners. Fourth, not everyone values a good reputation to the same extent.

good reputation, and less chance to be chosen as potential partners. Fourth, not everyone values a good reputation to the same extent. English Summary 128 English summary English Summary S ocial dilemmas emerge when people experience a conflict between their immediate personal interest and the long-term collective interest of the group

More information

Cooperation in Prisoner s Dilemma Game: Influence of Social Relations

Cooperation in Prisoner s Dilemma Game: Influence of Social Relations Cooperation in Prisoner s Dilemma Game: Influence of Social Relations Maurice Grinberg (mgrinberg@nbu.bg) Evgenia Hristova (ehristova@cogs.nbu.bg) Milena Borisova (borisova_milena@abv.bg) Department of

More information

The Evolution of Cooperation

The Evolution of Cooperation Cooperative Alliances Problems of Group Living The Evolution of Cooperation The problem of altruism Definition of reproductive altruism: An individual behaves in such a way as to enhance the reproduction

More information

European Journal of Personality. The Underlying Motives of Different Mixed-Motive Games

European Journal of Personality. The Underlying Motives of Different Mixed-Motive Games The Underlying Motives of Different Mixed-Motive Games Journal: European Journal of Personality Manuscript ID EJP-15-2034 Wiley - Manuscript type: Response Date Submitted by the Author: 16-Sep-2015 Complete

More information

Why Prosocials Exhibit Greater Cooperation

Why Prosocials Exhibit Greater Cooperation European Journal of Personality DOI: 10.1002/per.418 Why Prosocials Exhibit Greater Cooperation than Proselfs: The Roles of Social Responsibility and Reciprocity DAVID DE CREMER 1 * and PAUL A. M. VAN

More information

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION Supplementary Statistics and Results This file contains supplementary statistical information and a discussion of the interpretation of the belief effect on the basis of additional data. We also present

More information

Altruistic Behavior: Lessons from Neuroeconomics. Kei Yoshida Postdoctoral Research Fellow University of Tokyo Center for Philosophy (UTCP)

Altruistic Behavior: Lessons from Neuroeconomics. Kei Yoshida Postdoctoral Research Fellow University of Tokyo Center for Philosophy (UTCP) Altruistic Behavior: Lessons from Neuroeconomics Kei Yoshida Postdoctoral Research Fellow University of Tokyo Center for Philosophy (UTCP) Table of Contents 1. The Emergence of Neuroeconomics, or the Decline

More information

The Game Prisoners Really Play: Preference Elicitation and the Impact of Communication

The Game Prisoners Really Play: Preference Elicitation and the Impact of Communication The Game Prisoners Really Play: Preference Elicitation and the Impact of Communication Michael Kosfeld University of Zurich Ernst Fehr University of Zurich October 10, 2003 Unfinished version: Please do

More information

Veronika Grimm, Friederike Mengel. Let me sleep on it: Delay reduces rejection rates in Ultimatum Games RM/10/017

Veronika Grimm, Friederike Mengel. Let me sleep on it: Delay reduces rejection rates in Ultimatum Games RM/10/017 Veronika Grimm, Friederike Mengel Let me sleep on it: Delay reduces rejection rates in Ultimatum Games RM/10/017 Let me sleep on it: Delay reduces rejection rates in Ultimatum Games Veronika Grimm Friederike

More information

Groups in Organizations. Overview of topics

Groups in Organizations. Overview of topics Groups in Organizations Overview of topics 1 Plan of today s lecture Groups general aspects Links with individual behavior Cohesion & conformity Decision making in groups 2 Characteristics of Groups Groups

More information

Literature Henrich, Joseph, and Natalie Henrich Why Humans Cooperate A Cultural and Evolutionary Explanation. Oxford: Oxford University Press

Literature Henrich, Joseph, and Natalie Henrich Why Humans Cooperate A Cultural and Evolutionary Explanation. Oxford: Oxford University Press INSTITUTIONS AND INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN Erling Berge Henrich and Henrich 2007 Why Humans Cooperate Literature Henrich, Joseph, and Natalie Henrich. 2007. Why Humans Cooperate A Cultural and Evolutionary

More information

Irrationality in Game Theory

Irrationality in Game Theory Irrationality in Game Theory Yamin Htun Dec 9, 2005 Abstract The concepts in game theory have been evolving in such a way that existing theories are recasted to apply to problems that previously appeared

More information

Color Cues and Viscosity in. Iterated Prisoner s Dilemma

Color Cues and Viscosity in. Iterated Prisoner s Dilemma Color Cues and Viscosity in Iterated Prisoner s Dilemma Michael Joya University of British Columbia Abstract The presence of color tag cues and a viscous environment have each been shown to foster conditional

More information

Social Norms and Reciprocity*

Social Norms and Reciprocity* Social Norms and Reciprocity* Andreas Diekmann Institut für Soziologie Universität Bern Thomas Voss Institut für Soziologie Universität Leipzig [ March 2003 ] Paper presented on the session Solidarity

More information

The Evolution of Cooperation: The Genetic Algorithm Applied to Three Normal- Form Games

The Evolution of Cooperation: The Genetic Algorithm Applied to Three Normal- Form Games The Evolution of Cooperation: The Genetic Algorithm Applied to Three Normal- Form Games Scott Cederberg P.O. Box 595 Stanford, CA 949 (65) 497-7776 (cederber@stanford.edu) Abstract The genetic algorithm

More information

CONCEPT OF PROSOCIAL BEHAVIOR

CONCEPT OF PROSOCIAL BEHAVIOR FAQ CONCEPT OF PROSOCIAL BEHAVIOR 1Q: Explain prosocial behavior, helping behavior and altruism. What is the difference between helping behavior and altruism? Ans: As the word indicates, prosocial behavior

More information

24/10/13. Surprisingly little evidence that: sex offenders have enduring empathy deficits empathy interventions result in reduced reoffending.

24/10/13. Surprisingly little evidence that: sex offenders have enduring empathy deficits empathy interventions result in reduced reoffending. Professor Tony Ward Law, D. R. & Ward, T. (2011). Desistance from sexual offending: Alternatives to throwing away the keys. New York, NY: Guilford Press. Ward, T., & Durrant, R. (2011). Evolutionary behavioural

More information

Psychological Experience of Attitudinal Ambivalence as a Function of Manipulated Source of Conflict and Individual Difference in Self-Construal

Psychological Experience of Attitudinal Ambivalence as a Function of Manipulated Source of Conflict and Individual Difference in Self-Construal Seoul Journal of Business Volume 11, Number 1 (June 2005) Psychological Experience of Attitudinal Ambivalence as a Function of Manipulated Source of Conflict and Individual Difference in Self-Construal

More information

CONTENT ANALYSIS OF COGNITIVE BIAS: DEVELOPMENT OF A STANDARDIZED MEASURE Heather M. Hartman-Hall David A. F. Haaga

CONTENT ANALYSIS OF COGNITIVE BIAS: DEVELOPMENT OF A STANDARDIZED MEASURE Heather M. Hartman-Hall David A. F. Haaga Journal of Rational-Emotive & Cognitive-Behavior Therapy Volume 17, Number 2, Summer 1999 CONTENT ANALYSIS OF COGNITIVE BIAS: DEVELOPMENT OF A STANDARDIZED MEASURE Heather M. Hartman-Hall David A. F. Haaga

More information

Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game

Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game Effects of Sequential Context on Judgments and Decisions in the Prisoner s Dilemma Game Ivaylo Vlaev (ivaylo.vlaev@psy.ox.ac.uk) Department of Experimental Psychology, University of Oxford, Oxford, OX1

More information

Toward the Measurement of Interpersonal Generosity (IG): An IG Scale Conceptualized, Tested, and Validated Conceptual Definition

Toward the Measurement of Interpersonal Generosity (IG): An IG Scale Conceptualized, Tested, and Validated Conceptual Definition Toward the Measurement of Interpersonal Generosity (IG): An IG Scale Conceptualized, Tested, and Validated Christian Smith, University of Notre Dame Jonathan P. Hill, Calvin College 2009 The Interpersonal

More information

DIFFERENCES IN THE ECONOMIC DECISIONS OF MEN AND WOMEN: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE*

DIFFERENCES IN THE ECONOMIC DECISIONS OF MEN AND WOMEN: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE* DIFFERENCES IN THE ECONOMIC DECISIONS OF MEN AND WOMEN: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE* Catherine C. Eckel Department of Economics Virginia Tech Blacksburg, VA 24061-0316 Philip J. Grossman Department of Economics

More information

Feldexperimente in der Soziologie

Feldexperimente in der Soziologie Feldexperimente in der Soziologie Einführungsveranstaltung 04.02.2016 Seite 1 Content 1. Field Experiments 2. What Do Laboratory Experiments Measuring Social Preferences Reveal about the Real World? Lab

More information

Koji Kotani International University of Japan. Abstract

Koji Kotani International University of Japan. Abstract Further investigations of framing effects on cooperative choices in a provision point mechanism Koji Kotani International University of Japan Shunsuke Managi Yokohama National University Kenta Tanaka Yokohama

More information

Title. Author(s)Takahashi, Nobuyuki. Issue Date Doc URL. Type. Note. File Information. Adaptive Bases of Human Rationality

Title. Author(s)Takahashi, Nobuyuki. Issue Date Doc URL. Type. Note. File Information. Adaptive Bases of Human Rationality Title Adaptive Bases of Human Rationality Author(s)Takahashi, Nobuyuki SOCREAL 2007: Proceedings of the International Works CitationJapan, 2007 / editor Tomoyuki Yamada: 1(71)-34(104) Issue Date 2007 Doc

More information

Perceived criticality and contributions in public good dilemmas De Cremer, D.; van Dijk, E.

Perceived criticality and contributions in public good dilemmas De Cremer, D.; van Dijk, E. Tilburg University Perceived criticality and contributions in public good dilemmas De Cremer, D.; van Dijk, E. Published in: Group Processes and Intergroup Relations: GPIR Publication date: 2002 Link to

More information

By Olivia Smith and Steven van de Put Third Year, Second Prize

By Olivia Smith and Steven van de Put Third Year, Second Prize Are humans always the rational, self-interested agents that mainstream economics assumes them to be? Discuss, using ideas of reciprocity, altruism and fairness By Olivia Smith and Steven van de Put Third

More information

Supporting Information

Supporting Information Supporting Information Burton-Chellew and West 10.1073/pnas.1210960110 SI Results Fig. S4 A and B shows the percentage of free riders and cooperators over time for each treatment. Although Fig. S4A shows

More information

EUROPEAN ORTHODONTIC TEACHERS FORUM 2016

EUROPEAN ORTHODONTIC TEACHERS FORUM 2016 EUROPEAN ORTHODONTIC TEACHERS FORUM 2016 Teach the Teacher Fostering Resident Autonomy by Adopting a Coaching Approach to Teaching How do you know when a resident is ready to function autonomously? How

More information

HOW TO IDENTIFY A RESEARCH QUESTION? How to Extract a Question from a Topic that Interests You?

HOW TO IDENTIFY A RESEARCH QUESTION? How to Extract a Question from a Topic that Interests You? Stefan Götze, M.A., M.Sc. LMU HOW TO IDENTIFY A RESEARCH QUESTION? I How to Extract a Question from a Topic that Interests You? I assume you currently have only a vague notion about the content of your

More information

UNIT 1. THE DIGNITY OF THE PERSON

UNIT 1. THE DIGNITY OF THE PERSON Ethical Values 3ºESO Department of Philosophy IES Nicolás Copérnico UNIT 1. THE DIGNITY OF THE PERSON 1. What is a person? The Universal Declaration of Human Rights concedes the status of person to every

More information

Jakub Steiner The University of Edinburgh. Abstract

Jakub Steiner The University of Edinburgh. Abstract A trace of anger is enough: on the enforcement of social norms Jakub Steiner The University of Edinburgh Abstract It is well documented that the possibility of punishing free-riders increases contributions

More information

How to identify trust and reciprocity

How to identify trust and reciprocity Games and Economic Behavior 46 (2004) 260 281 www.elsevier.com/locate/geb How to identify trust and reciprocity JamesC.Cox Department of Economics, 401 McClelland Hall, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ

More information

Implicit Information in Directionality of Verbal Probability Expressions

Implicit Information in Directionality of Verbal Probability Expressions Implicit Information in Directionality of Verbal Probability Expressions Hidehito Honda (hito@ky.hum.titech.ac.jp) Kimihiko Yamagishi (kimihiko@ky.hum.titech.ac.jp) Graduate School of Decision Science

More information

Emergence of Cooperative Societies in Evolutionary Games Using a Social Orientation Model

Emergence of Cooperative Societies in Evolutionary Games Using a Social Orientation Model Emergence of Cooperative Societies in Evolutionary Games Using a Social Orientation Model Kan-Leung Cheng Abstract We utilize evolutionary game theory to study the evolution of cooperative societies and

More information

Contributions and Beliefs in Liner Public Goods Experiment: Difference between Partners and Strangers Design

Contributions and Beliefs in Liner Public Goods Experiment: Difference between Partners and Strangers Design Working Paper Contributions and Beliefs in Liner Public Goods Experiment: Difference between Partners and Strangers Design Tsuyoshi Nihonsugi 1, 2 1 Research Fellow of the Japan Society for the Promotion

More information

Introduction to Game Theory Autonomous Agents and MultiAgent Systems 2015/2016

Introduction to Game Theory Autonomous Agents and MultiAgent Systems 2015/2016 Introduction to Game Theory Autonomous Agents and MultiAgent Systems 2015/2016 Ana Paiva * These slides are based on the book by Prof. M. Woodridge An Introduction to Multiagent Systems and the online

More information

Professor Tony Ward. Empathy, altruism and the treatment of sex offenders.

Professor Tony Ward. Empathy, altruism and the treatment of sex offenders. Professor Tony Ward Empathy, altruism and the treatment of sex offenders. Key References Law, D. R. & Ward, T. (2011). Desistance from sexual offending: Alternatives to throwing away the keys. New York,

More information

Affective Social Ties without the Need to Belong?

Affective Social Ties without the Need to Belong? RMM Vol. 4, 2013, 20 27 Special Topic: Coevolving Relationships between Political Science and Economics Edited by Herbert David, Hartmut Kliemt and Elinor Ostrom http://www.rmm-journal.de/ Matthias Greiff

More information

Social goals as triggers of cooperation: How reciprocity and group solidarity encourage cooperative behavior in a public goods game

Social goals as triggers of cooperation: How reciprocity and group solidarity encourage cooperative behavior in a public goods game Social goals as triggers of cooperation: How reciprocity and group solidarity encourage cooperative behavior in a public goods game Dr. Julie Urda Rhode Island College Providence, RI, USA jurda@ric.edu

More information

Conditional behavior affects the level of evolved cooperation in public good games

Conditional behavior affects the level of evolved cooperation in public good games Center for the Study of Institutional Diversity CSID Working Paper Series #CSID-2013-007 Conditional behavior affects the level of evolved cooperation in public good games Marco A. Janssen Arizona State

More information

Car Versus Public Transportation? The Role of Social Value Orientations in a Real-Life Social Dilemma1

Car Versus Public Transportation? The Role of Social Value Orientations in a Real-Life Social Dilemma1 Car Versus Public Transportation? The Role of Social Value Orientations in a Real-Life Social Dilemma1 MARK VAN vugt2 AND REE M. MEERTENS Department of Health Education University of Limburg Maastricht.

More information

Behavioral Game Theory

Behavioral Game Theory Outline (September 3, 2007) Outline (September 3, 2007) Introduction Outline (September 3, 2007) Introduction Examples of laboratory experiments Outline (September 3, 2007) Introduction Examples of laboratory

More information

The Evolutionary Foundations of Strong Reciprocity

The Evolutionary Foundations of Strong Reciprocity Analyse & Kritik 29/2005 ( c Lucius & Lucius, Stuttgart) p. xxx xxx J. McKenzie Alexander The Evolutionary Foundations of Strong Reciprocity To say that people cooperate, trust, offer more than is logically

More information

Empathy and Negative Reciprocity as Predictors of Third-Party Punishment

Empathy and Negative Reciprocity as Predictors of Third-Party Punishment University at Albany, State University of New York Scholars Archive Psychology Honors College 5-2018 Empathy and Negative Reciprocity as Predictors of Third-Party Punishment Olivia Johansen University

More information

reward based power have ability to give you what you want. coercive have power to punish

reward based power have ability to give you what you want. coercive have power to punish Chapter 7 Finding and Using Negotiation Power Why Power Important to Negotiators? Seeking power in negotiations from 1 of 2 perceptions: 1. Negotiator believes he has less power than other party 2. Negotiator

More information

Answers to end of chapter questions

Answers to end of chapter questions Answers to end of chapter questions Chapter 1 What are the three most important characteristics of QCA as a method of data analysis? QCA is (1) systematic, (2) flexible, and (3) it reduces data. What are

More information

Using a Social Orientation Model for the Evolution of Cooperative Societies

Using a Social Orientation Model for the Evolution of Cooperative Societies 2010 IEEE/WIC/ACM International Conference on Web Intelligence and Intelligent Agent Technology Using a Social Orientation Model for the Evolution of Cooperative Societies Kan-Leung Cheng, Inon Zuckerman,

More information

Sequential Decision and Strategy Vector Methods in Ultimatum Bargaining: Evidence on the Strength of Other- Regarding Behavior

Sequential Decision and Strategy Vector Methods in Ultimatum Bargaining: Evidence on the Strength of Other- Regarding Behavior Department of Economics Discussion Paper 2004-04 Sequential Decision and Strategy Vector Methods in Ultimatum Bargaining: Evidence on the Strength of Other- Regarding Behavior Robert J. Oxoby University

More information

Social Utility in Ultimatum Bargaining

Social Utility in Ultimatum Bargaining Social Justice Research, Vol. 16, No. 3, September 2003 ( C 2003) Social Utility in Ultimatum Bargaining Michel J. J. Handgraaf, 1,4 Eric Van Dijk, 2 and David De Cremer 3 In this article we will provide

More information

Today s lecture. A thought experiment. Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness. Overview readings: Fehr and Fischbacher (2002) Sobel (2005)

Today s lecture. A thought experiment. Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness. Overview readings: Fehr and Fischbacher (2002) Sobel (2005) Topic 3: Social preferences and fairness Are we perfectly selfish? If not, does it affect economic analysis? How to take it into account? Overview readings: Fehr and Fischbacher (2002) Sobel (2005) Today

More information

PLANNING THE RESEARCH PROJECT

PLANNING THE RESEARCH PROJECT Van Der Velde / Guide to Business Research Methods First Proof 6.11.2003 4:53pm page 1 Part I PLANNING THE RESEARCH PROJECT Van Der Velde / Guide to Business Research Methods First Proof 6.11.2003 4:53pm

More information

Pearson Education Limited Edinburgh Gate Harlow Essex CM20 2JE England and Associated Companies throughout the world

Pearson Education Limited Edinburgh Gate Harlow Essex CM20 2JE England and Associated Companies throughout the world Pearson Education Limited Edinburgh Gate Harlow Essex CM20 2JE England and Associated Companies throughout the world Visit us on the World Wide Web at: www.pearsoned.co.uk Pearson Education Limited 2014

More information

WILL HOMO ECONOMICUS SURVIVE?

WILL HOMO ECONOMICUS SURVIVE? WILL HOMO ECONOMICUS SURVIVE? PHILIPP DOERRENBERG Erasmus Student In this essay, Philipp Doerrenberg highlights recent experimental work that has proven the shaky foundations of the concept of the rational,

More information

The influence of (in)congruence of communicator expertise and trustworthiness on acceptance of CCS technologies

The influence of (in)congruence of communicator expertise and trustworthiness on acceptance of CCS technologies The influence of (in)congruence of communicator expertise and trustworthiness on acceptance of CCS technologies Emma ter Mors 1,2, Mieneke Weenig 1, Naomi Ellemers 1, Dancker Daamen 1 1 Leiden University,

More information

VERDIN MANUSCRIPT REVIEW HISTORY REVISION NOTES FROM AUTHORS (ROUND 2)

VERDIN MANUSCRIPT REVIEW HISTORY REVISION NOTES FROM AUTHORS (ROUND 2) 1 VERDIN MANUSCRIPT REVIEW HISTORY REVISION NOTES FROM AUTHORS (ROUND 2) Thank you for providing us with the opportunity to revise our paper. We have revised the manuscript according to the editors and

More information

SOCI 323 Social Psychology

SOCI 323 Social Psychology SOCI 323 Session 7 Theories of Attribution Lecturer: Dr. Peace Mamle Tetteh, Department of Sociology Contact Information: ptetteh@ug.edu.gh College of Education School of Continuing and Distance Education

More information

Institutions and Cooperative Behavior

Institutions and Cooperative Behavior Institutions and Cooperative Behavior by Arild Vatn Department of International Environmental and Development Studies Norwegian University of Life Sciences Complexity Economics for Sustainability Seminar

More information

Strong Reciprocity and Human Sociality

Strong Reciprocity and Human Sociality Notes on Behavioral Economics 1 Strong Reciprocity and Human Sociality Human groups are highly social despite a low level of relatedness. There is an empirically identifiable form of prosocial behavior

More information

VIRGINIA LAW REVIEW IN BRIEF

VIRGINIA LAW REVIEW IN BRIEF VIRGINIA LAW REVIEW IN BRIEF VOLUME 96 JUNE 15, 2010 PAGES 35 39 REPLY GOOD INTENTIONS MATTER Katharine T. Bartlett * W HILE writing the article to which Professors Mitchell and Bielby have published responses,

More information

Homo economicus is dead! How do we know how the mind works? How the mind works

Homo economicus is dead! How do we know how the mind works? How the mind works Some facts about social preferences, or why we're sometimes nice and sometimes not Karthik Panchanathan buddha@ucla.edu Homo economicus is dead! It was a mistake to believe that individuals and institutions

More information

Prior Dispositions and Actual Behavior in Dictator and Ultimatum Games. Abstract

Prior Dispositions and Actual Behavior in Dictator and Ultimatum Games. Abstract Prior Dispositions and Actual Behavior in Dictator and Ultimatum Games Hermann Brandstätter, University of Linz Werner Güth, Humboldt-University, Berlin Judith Himmelbauer, University of Linz Willy Kriz,

More information

Thoughts on Social Design

Thoughts on Social Design 577 Center for Mathematical Economics Working Papers September 2017 Thoughts on Social Design Walter Trockel and Claus-Jochen Haake Center for Mathematical Economics(IMW) Bielefeld University Universitätsstraße

More information

Commuting by car or public transportation? A social dilemma analysis of travel mode judgements

Commuting by car or public transportation? A social dilemma analysis of travel mode judgements European Journal of Social Psychology, Vol. 26, 373-395 (1996) Commuting by car or public transportation? A social dilemma analysis of travel mode judgements MARK VAN VUGT Department of Psychology, University

More information

Tilburg University. Social value orientations and the strategic use of fairness in ultimatum bargaining van Dijk, E.; De Cremer, D.; Handgraaf, M.J.J.

Tilburg University. Social value orientations and the strategic use of fairness in ultimatum bargaining van Dijk, E.; De Cremer, D.; Handgraaf, M.J.J. Tilburg University Social value orientations and the strategic use of fairness in ultimatum bargaining van Dijk, E.; De Cremer, D.; Handgraaf, M.J.J. Published in: Journal of Experimental Social Psychology

More information

Positive reciprocity and intentions in trust games

Positive reciprocity and intentions in trust games Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization Vol. 52 (2003) 267 275 Positive reciprocity and intentions in trust games Kevin A. McCabe a, Mary L. Rigdon b,, Vernon L. Smith a a Interdisciplinary Center

More information

To conclude, a theory of error must be a theory of the interaction between human performance variability and the situational constraints.

To conclude, a theory of error must be a theory of the interaction between human performance variability and the situational constraints. The organisers have provided us with a both stimulating and irritating list of questions relating to the topic of the conference: Human Error. My first intention was to try to answer the questions one

More information

Underlying Theory & Basic Issues

Underlying Theory & Basic Issues Underlying Theory & Basic Issues Dewayne E Perry ENS 623 Perry@ece.utexas.edu 1 All Too True 2 Validity In software engineering, we worry about various issues: E-Type systems: Usefulness is it doing what

More information

Book review: The Calculus of Selfishness, by Karl Sigmund

Book review: The Calculus of Selfishness, by Karl Sigmund Book review: The Calculus of Selfishness, by Karl Sigmund Olle Häggström Leading game theorist Karl Sigmund calls his latest book The Calculus of Selfishness, although arguably The Calculus of Cooperation

More information

How to Cope with Noise In the Iterated Prisoner's Dilemma

How to Cope with Noise In the Iterated Prisoner's Dilemma How to Cope with Noise In the Iterated Prisoner's Dilemma Jianzhong Wu Institute of Automation Chinese Academy of Sciences and Robert Axelrod Institute of Public Policy Studies University of Michigan July

More information

2 Types of psychological tests and their validity, precision and standards

2 Types of psychological tests and their validity, precision and standards 2 Types of psychological tests and their validity, precision and standards Tests are usually classified in objective or projective, according to Pasquali (2008). In case of projective tests, a person is

More information

Asking and answering research questions. What s it about?

Asking and answering research questions. What s it about? 2 Asking and answering research questions What s it about? (Social Psychology pp. 24 54) Social psychologists strive to reach general conclusions by developing scientific theories about why people behave

More information

Social inclusion as recognition? My purpose here is not to advocate for recognition paradigm as a superior way of defining/defending SI.

Social inclusion as recognition? My purpose here is not to advocate for recognition paradigm as a superior way of defining/defending SI. Social inclusion as recognition? My purpose here is not to advocate for recognition paradigm as a superior way of defining/defending SI. My purpose is just reflective: given tradition of thought and conceptual

More information

An International Study of the Reliability and Validity of Leadership/Impact (L/I)

An International Study of the Reliability and Validity of Leadership/Impact (L/I) An International Study of the Reliability and Validity of Leadership/Impact (L/I) Janet L. Szumal, Ph.D. Human Synergistics/Center for Applied Research, Inc. Contents Introduction...3 Overview of L/I...5

More information

Using Experimental Methods to Inform Public Policy Debates. Jim Murphy Presentation to ISER July 13, 2006

Using Experimental Methods to Inform Public Policy Debates. Jim Murphy Presentation to ISER July 13, 2006 Using Experimental Methods to Inform Public Policy Debates Jim Murphy Presentation to ISER July 13, 2006 Experiments are just one more tool for the applied economist Econometric analysis of nonexperimental

More information

Reactions to group success and failure as a function of identification level de Cremer, D.; van Dijk, E.

Reactions to group success and failure as a function of identification level de Cremer, D.; van Dijk, E. Tilburg University Reactions to group success and failure as a function of identification level de Cremer, D.; van Dijk, E. Published in: Journal of Experimental Social Psychology Publication date: 2002

More information

Adverse Impact of Fairness on Efficient Outcomes of. Resource Allocation Decisions

Adverse Impact of Fairness on Efficient Outcomes of. Resource Allocation Decisions Adverse Impact of Fairness on Efficient Outcomes of Resource Allocation Decisions Lars-Olof Johansson Mathias Gustafsson Lars Olsson, Tommy Gärling Göteborg University, Sweden Two experiments were conducted

More information

Further Properties of the Priority Rule

Further Properties of the Priority Rule Further Properties of the Priority Rule Michael Strevens Draft of July 2003 Abstract In Strevens (2003), I showed that science s priority system for distributing credit promotes an allocation of labor

More information

Incentive compatibility in stated preference valuation methods

Incentive compatibility in stated preference valuation methods Incentive compatibility in stated preference valuation methods Ewa Zawojska Faculty of Economic Sciences University of Warsaw Summary of research accomplishments presented in the doctoral thesis Assessing

More information

Chapter 2 Various Types of Social Dilemma

Chapter 2 Various Types of Social Dilemma Chapter 2 Various Types of Social Dilemma In order to examine the pragmatic methods of solving social dilemmas, it is important to understand the logical structure of dilemmas that underpin actual real-life

More information

Writing Reaction Papers Using the QuALMRI Framework

Writing Reaction Papers Using the QuALMRI Framework Writing Reaction Papers Using the QuALMRI Framework Modified from Organizing Scientific Thinking Using the QuALMRI Framework Written by Kevin Ochsner and modified by others. Based on a scheme devised by

More information

social preferences P000153

social preferences P000153 P000153 Behaviour in a variety of games is inconsistent with the traditional formulation of egoistic decision-makers; however, the observed differences are often systematic and robust. In many cases, people

More information

FEEDBACK TUTORIAL LETTER

FEEDBACK TUTORIAL LETTER FEEDBACK TUTORIAL LETTER 1 ST SEMESTER 2017 ASSIGNMENT 2 ORGANISATIONAL BEHAVIOUR OSB611S 1 Page1 OSB611S - FEEDBACK TUTORIAL LETTER FOR ASSIGNMENT 2-2016 Dear student The purpose of this tutorial letter

More information

Reply to Binmore: Social Norms or Social Preferences? Herbert Gintis

Reply to Binmore: Social Norms or Social Preferences? Herbert Gintis Reply to Binmore: Social Norms or Social Preferences? Herbert Gintis May 25, 2011 I am in agreement with many of Ken Binmore s remarks in Social Norms and Social Preferences (2010). Like Binmore, I welcome

More information

Defining Psychology Behaviorism: Social Psychology: Milgram s Obedience Studies Bystander Non-intervention Cognitive Psychology:

Defining Psychology Behaviorism: Social Psychology: Milgram s Obedience Studies Bystander Non-intervention Cognitive Psychology: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Defining Psychology Behaviorism: The scientific study of how rewards and punishment in the environment affect human and non-human behavior Empirical approach: vary contingencies of

More information

Experimental examination of reputation of collective sanctioners

Experimental examination of reputation of collective sanctioners Experimental examination of reputation of collective sanctioners Rie Mashima (Kumamoto Gakuen University) Nobuyuki Takahashi (Hokkaido University) E-mail: mashima@kumagaku.ac.jp Although sanctioning is

More information

Team Reasoning and a Rank-Based Function of Team s Interests

Team Reasoning and a Rank-Based Function of Team s Interests Team Reasoning and a Rank-Based Function of Team s Interests Jurgis Karpus Mantas Radzvilas April 2015 Abstract Orthodox game theory is sometimes criticized for its failure to single out intuitively compelling

More information

Author's personal copy

Author's personal copy Exp Econ DOI 10.1007/s10683-015-9466-8 ORIGINAL PAPER The effects of endowment size and strategy method on third party punishment Jillian Jordan 1 Katherine McAuliffe 1,2 David Rand 1,3,4 Received: 19

More information

Might over Morality: Social Values and the Perception of Other Players in Experimental Games

Might over Morality: Social Values and the Perception of Other Players in Experimental Games JOURNAL OF EXPERIMENTAL SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY 22, 203-215 (1986) Might over Morality: Social Values and the Perception of Other Players in Experimental Games WIM B. G. LIEBRAND, RONALD W. T. L. JANSEN, VICTOR

More information

Sense-making Approach in Determining Health Situation, Information Seeking and Usage

Sense-making Approach in Determining Health Situation, Information Seeking and Usage DOI: 10.7763/IPEDR. 2013. V62. 16 Sense-making Approach in Determining Health Situation, Information Seeking and Usage Ismail Sualman 1 and Rosni Jaafar 1 Faculty of Communication and Media Studies, Universiti

More information

CHAPTER 15. Social Psychology. Lecture Overview. Introductory Definition PSYCHOLOGY PSYCHOLOGY PSYCHOLOGY. Social Cognition.

CHAPTER 15. Social Psychology. Lecture Overview. Introductory Definition PSYCHOLOGY PSYCHOLOGY PSYCHOLOGY. Social Cognition. Social Psychology CHAPTER 15 Social Cognition Lecture Overview Social Influence Social Relations Applying Social Psychology to Social Problems Introductory Definition Social Psychology: scientific study

More information

Chapter 13. Social Psychology

Chapter 13. Social Psychology Social Psychology Psychology, Fifth Edition, James S. Nairne What s It For? Social Psychology Interpreting the Behavior of Others Behaving in the Presence of Others Establishing Relations With Others Social

More information

IN THE iterated prisoner s dilemma (IPD), two players

IN THE iterated prisoner s dilemma (IPD), two players IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON EVOLUTIONARY COMPUTATION, VOL. 11, NO. 6, DECEMBER 2007 689 Multiple Choices and Reputation in Multiagent Interactions Siang Yew Chong, Member, IEEE, and Xin Yao, Fellow, IEEE Abstract

More information

Is Leisure Theory Needed For Leisure Studies?

Is Leisure Theory Needed For Leisure Studies? Journal of Leisure Research Copyright 2000 2000, Vol. 32, No. 1, pp. 138-142 National Recreation and Park Association Is Leisure Theory Needed For Leisure Studies? KEYWORDS: Mark S. Searle College of Human

More information

Misleading Postevent Information and the Memory Impairment Hypothesis: Comment on Belli and Reply to Tversky and Tuchin

Misleading Postevent Information and the Memory Impairment Hypothesis: Comment on Belli and Reply to Tversky and Tuchin Journal of Experimental Psychology: General 1989, Vol. 118, No. 1,92-99 Copyright 1989 by the American Psychological Association, Im 0096-3445/89/S00.7 Misleading Postevent Information and the Memory Impairment

More information

MACHIAVELLIANISM, DISCUSSION TIME, AND GROUP SHIFT. HELMUT LAMM Universitat Mannheim. DAVID G. MYERS Hope College

MACHIAVELLIANISM, DISCUSSION TIME, AND GROUP SHIFT. HELMUT LAMM Universitat Mannheim. DAVID G. MYERS Hope College SOCIAL BEHAVIOR AND PERSONALITY, 1976, 4(1), 41-48 Society for Personality Research Inc. DOI 10.2224/sbp.1976.4.1.41 MACHIAVELLIANISM, DISCUSSION TIME, AND GROUP SHIFT HELMUT LAMM Universitat Mannheim

More information